2420 Views
370 Downloads |
The impact of macroprudential policy on financial stability in selected EU countries*
Article | Year: 2022 | Pages: 141 - 170 | Volume: 46 | Issue: 1 Received: March 5, 2021 | Accepted: October 1, 2021 | Published online: March 8, 2022
|
FULL ARTICLE
FIGURES & DATA
REFERENCES
CROSSMARK POLICY
METRICS
LICENCING
PDF
|
d(CGR)
|
d(HPGR)
|
d(DEG)
|
d(CET)
|
d(LDR)
|
d(LR)
|
d(NDF)
|
d(CR)
|
d(INR)
|
Mean
|
-1.97
|
0.04
|
0.59
|
0.08
|
1.16
|
-0.12
|
-0.02
|
0.17
|
-0.17
|
Median
|
-1.22
|
-0.10
|
0.24
|
0.12
|
0.90
|
-0.07
|
-0.02
|
-0.11
|
-0.15
|
Maximum
|
80.41
|
7.10
|
18.11
|
2.03
|
13.99
|
1.07
|
1.32
|
17.96
|
3.44
|
Minimum
|
-34.33
|
-4.90
|
-4.79
|
-2.16
|
-6.65
|
-3.79
|
-1.38
|
-10.47
|
-2.69
|
Standard deviation
|
10.80
|
2.23
|
2.37
|
0.54
|
3.46
|
0.61
|
0.44
|
2.79
|
0.77
|
Skewness
|
4.16
|
0.45
|
4.88
|
-0.10
|
0.99
|
-2.15
|
0.36
|
2.88
|
0.77
|
Kurtosis
|
37.63
|
3.72
|
35.66
|
6.91
|
5.66
|
14.82
|
4.98
|
23.08
|
8.74
|
Jarque-Bera
|
5,074.44
|
5.38
|
4,648.03
|
61.22
|
43.92
|
632.61
|
17.68
|
1,746.59
|
141.32
|
Probability
|
0.00
|
0.07
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
Sum
|
-189.22
|
3.60
|
56.73
|
8.08
|
111.21
|
-11.90
|
-2.19
|
16.69
|
-16.60
|
Sum sq. dev.
|
11,089.82
|
470.89
|
531.76
|
28.07
|
1,136.47
|
35.75
|
18.11
|
737.41
|
56.32
|
Obser.
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
96
|
Notes: “d” denotes the first difference of a variable. For instance, d(CGR) denotes the first difference of CGR.Source: Authors’ calculations.
Response and explanatory variables
|
ADF-Fisher Chi-square statistic
(ADF-Fisher Chi-square probability)
|
Level (x)
|
First difference d(x)
|
CGR
|
13.2965
(0.3479)
|
70.8197
(0.0000)
|
HPGR
|
74.8063
(0.0000)
|
88.6962
(0.0000)
|
DEG
|
15.3016
(0.2254)
|
71.0383
(0.0000)
|
CET
|
11.9982
(0.4458)
|
71.0925
(0.0000)
|
LDR
|
11.0842
(0.5217)
|
47.9746
(0.0000)
|
LR
|
6.74768
(0.8738)
|
71.2775
(0.0000)
|
NDF
|
10.2671
(0.5925)
|
35.9455
(0.0003)
|
CR
|
5.87756
(0.9221)
|
54.8494
(0.0000)
|
INR
|
4.92658
(0.9604)
|
88.1111
(0.0000)
|
Notes: p-values for the Fisher-ADF panel unit root test are computed using the asymptotic Chi-square distribution and given in brackets. The maximum number of lags was automatically selected with Schwarz Information Criterion. Source: Authors’ calculations.
Model no.
|
Response
variable
|
Explanatory
variable/statistics
|
Cross-section
fixed effects
|
Period fixed
effects
|
Cross-section
fixed effects and period fixed effects
|
Period random
effects
|
1
|
DCGR
|
C
|
-0.678
(-0.595)
(0.553)
|
-0.991
(-0.991)
(0.369)
|
-0.833
(-0.757)
(0.451)
|
-0.844
(-0.644)
(0.521)
|
|
|
DCET
|
-4.353
(-1.971)
(0.052)*
|
-5.844
(-2.479)
(0.016)**
|
-5.533
(-2.350)
(0.022)**
|
-5.128
(-2.358)
(0.021)**
|
|
|
DINR
|
2.990
(1.971)
(0.052)*
|
0.670
(0.390)
(0.698)
|
0.766
(0.436)
(0.664)
|
2.298
(1.536)
(0.128)
|
|
|
DLDR
|
-0.541
(-1.699)
(0.093)*
|
-0.635
(-2.004)
(0.049)**
|
-0.707
(-2.138)
(0.036)**
|
-0.523
(-1.742)
(0.085)*
|
|
|
DNDF
|
-8.058
(-3.322)
(0.001)***
|
-7.599
(-3.209)
(0.002)***
|
-8.081
(-3.338)
(0.001)***
|
-7.666
(-3.344)
(0.001)***
|
|
|
DLR
|
-0.347
(-0.151)
(0.880)
|
-1.598
(-0.720)
(0.474)
|
-0.883
(-0.374)
(0.710)
|
-1.095
(-0.518)
(0.606)
|
|
|
DCR
|
-0.058
(-0.134)
(0.894)
|
-0.044
(-0.107)
(0.915)
|
-0.079
(-0.178)
(0.859)
|
-0.017
(-0.044)
(0.965)
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.243
|
0.397
|
0.442
|
0.194
|
|
|
S.E.
of regression
|
9.998
|
9.503
|
9.470
|
9.580
|
|
|
F-statistic
|
2.450
|
2.324
|
2.102
|
3.571
|
|
|
Prob.
(F-statistic)
|
0.011
|
0.004
|
0.008
|
0.003
|
|
|
Sum
squared resid
|
8396.389
|
6682.217
|
6188.189
|
8168.947
|
|
|
Durbin-Watson
stat
|
1.567
|
1.467
|
1.573
|
1.454
|
|
|
Redundant
fixed effects
test (F prob.)
|
0.368
|
0.085
|
0.099
|
-
|
|
|
Hausman
correlated random effects test
(Chi-square prob.)
|
-
|
-
|
-
|
0.280
|
|
|
Kleinbergen-Paap
test
|
-
|
-
|
(0.003)
|
(0.000)
|
|
|
Hansen-Sargan
test
|
-
|
-
|
(0.578)
|
(0.691)
|
2
|
DHPGR
|
C
|
-0.157
(-0.599)
(0.551)
|
-0.073
(-0.309)
(0.758)
|
-0.142
(-0.560)
(0.577)
|
-0.108
(-0.329)
(0.743)
|
|
|
DCET
|
0.482
(0.952)
(0.344)
|
-0.109
(-0.215)
(0.831)
|
0.497
(1.011)
(0.315)
|
0.200
(0.417)
(0.678)
|
|
|
DINR
|
-0.482
(-1.384)
(0.170)
|
-0.558
(-1.504)
(0.137)
|
-0.505
(-1.515)
(0.133)
|
-0.533
(-1.598)
(0.114)
|
|
|
DLDR
|
0.059
(0.807)
(0.422)
|
0.012
(0.178)
(0.859)
|
0.050
(0.724)
(0.471)
|
0.031
(0.469)
(0.640)
|
|
|
DNDF
|
-0.607
(-1.090)
(0.279)
|
-0.344
(-0.673)
(0.503)
|
-0.627
(-1.183)
(0.240)
|
-0.483
(-0.967)
(0.336)
|
|
|
DLR
|
0.129
(0.245)
(0.807)
|
0.042
(0.088)
(0.930)
|
0.232
(0.478)
(0.634)
|
0.137
(0.295)
(0.769)
|
|
|
DCR
|
0.024
(0.238)
(0.813)
|
0.040
(0.443)
(0.659)
|
0.040
(0.444)
(0.658)
|
0.039
(0.456)
(0.649)
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.061
|
0.337
|
0.057
|
0.043
|
|
|
S.E.
of regression
|
2.294
|
2.053
|
2.234
|
2.051
|
|
|
F-statistic
|
0.500
|
1.794
|
0.890
|
0.672
|
|
|
Prob.
(F-statistic)
|
0.898
|
0.035
|
0.506
|
0.673
|
|
|
Sum
squared resid
|
441.967
|
312.018
|
444.238
|
374.423
|
|
|
Durbin-Watson
stat
|
2.886
|
3.026
|
2.870
|
2.937
|
|
|
Redundant
fixed effects
test (F prob.)
|
0.995
|
0.032
|
0.113
|
-
|
|
|
Hausman
correlated random effects test
(Chi-square prob.)
|
-
|
-
|
-
|
0.446
|
|
|
Kleinbergen-Paap
test
|
-
|
-
|
(0.009)
|
(0.000)
|
|
|
Hansen-Sargan
test
|
-
|
-
|
(0.487)
|
(0.542)
|
3
|
DDEG
|
C
|
0.726
(2.908)
(0.005)***
|
0.687384
(2.655870)
(0.0097)***
|
0.712206
(2.834312)
(0.0060)***
|
0.701930
(2.606203)
(0.0107)**
|
|
|
DCET
|
-0.409
(-0.846)
(0.400)
|
-0.613586
(-1.103253)
(0.274)
|
-0.647117
(-1.203163)
(0.233)
|
-0.393038
(-0.785712)
(0.434)
|
|
|
DINR
|
0.244
(0.734)
(0.465)-
|
0.002
(0.005)
(0.996)-
|
-0.060
(-0.151)
(0.881)
|
0.230
(0.675)
(0.502)
|
|
|
DLDR
|
-0.103
(-1.476)
(0.144)
|
-0.087
(-1.164)
(0.248)
|
-0.125
(-1.653)
(0.103)
|
-0.076
(-1.097)
(0.276)
|
|
|
DNDF
|
-2.111
(-3.968)
(0.000)***
|
-2.034
(-3.642)
(0.001)***
|
-2.184
(-3.950)
(0.000)***
|
-1.970
(-3.682)
(0.000)***
|
|
|
DLR
|
-0.109
(-0.216)
(0.829)
|
-0.174
(-0.332)
(0.741)
|
-0.181
(-0.336)
(0.738)
|
-0.097
(-0.197)
(0.844)
|
|
|
DCR
|
-0.004
(-0.047)
(0.963
|
-0.066
(-0.676)
(0.501)
|
-0.027
(-0.269)
(0.789)
|
-0.038
(-0.416)
(0.678)
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.241
|
0.301
|
0.393
|
0.155
|
|
|
S.E.
of regression
|
2.192
|
2.241
|
2.163
|
2.226
|
|
|
F-statistic
|
2.422
|
1.517
|
1.717
|
2.716
|
|
|
Prob.
(F-statistic)
|
0.011
|
0.098
|
0.039
|
0.018
|
|
|
Sum
squared resid
|
403.705
|
371.753
|
322.844
|
441.087
|
|
|
Durbin-Watson
stat
|
2.025
|
1.772
|
2.024
|
1.822
|
|
|
Redundant
fixed effects
test (F prob.)
|
0.077
|
0.330
|
0.169
|
|
|
|
Hausman
correlated random effects test
(Chi-square prob.)
|
-
|
-
|
-
|
0.570
|
|
|
Kleinbergen-Paap
test
|
-
|
-
|
(0.006)
|
(0.000)
|
|
|
Hansen-Sargan
test
|
-
|
-
|
(0.7285)
|
(0.815)
|
Notes: Cross-section random effects and cross-section random effects and period random effects were not possible to estimate, since random effects estimation requires number of cross sections > number of coefs for between estimator for estimate of RE innovation variance. In the table, all regressors and regressands have a »D« in front of their name (e.g., CGR becomes DCGR), since all variables are taken at first difference for stationarity. The t-statistics are given in brackets below the coefficients and the p-values are in brackets below the t-statistics. Significance levels are denoted as: *** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%, * significant at 10%. Source: Authors’ calculations. Kleibergen-Paap test and Hansen-Sargan test were carried out with STATA 12 version. The rest of the analyses were conducted in EViews version 11.
Author(s)
|
Economies
|
Methodology
|
Results
|
Davis, Liadze and Piggott (2019)
|
UK, Italy and Germany
|
National Institute's Global
Econometric Model, NiGEM. NiGEM is a global econometric model, and most
countries in the EU and the OECD, as well as major emerging markets, are
modelled individually. The rest of the world is modelled through a set of
regional blocks so that the model is global in scope. Macroprudential policy
is incorporated in NiGEM. There are three simulations/shocks in the models:
Tightening of loan-to-value policy; increase in risk-adjusted capital
adequacy target; and historic dynamic simulation for the crisis period.
|
The loan-to-value simulation
predominantly impacts consumption and the housing market, whereas the capital
adequacy simulation has a more significant effect on investment and output.
Both simulations increase bank capital ratios and curb bank lending. The
findings of the study suggest that, overall, the loan-to-value tool has a
lower effect than capital adequacy on the probability of a banking crisis occurring
and leads to lower net benefits. The introduction of macroprudential policy
measures before the onset of the crisis leads to an improvement in key
macroeconomic measures and might therefore prevent the crisis from
materializing.
|
Carreras, Davis and Piggott (2018)
|
19 OECD countries
|
Cointegration framework;
Vector-Error-Correction (VECM), Vector Autoregression (VAR), Fully- Modified
OLS (FMOLS) and Seemingly-Unrelated (SUR) estimation.
A comparison of results from
cointegration with non-cointegrating specifications.
|
Macroprudential policy instruments
(taxes on financial institutions, capital requirements, loan to value ratios,
debt to income ratio limits, limits on foreign currency lending, limits on
interbank exposures and concentration limits) have a positive impact on
stalling household credit growth and house prices in both short-run and
long-run. Tools such as limits on debt-to-income ratios are more effective
for limiting house price growth, whilst tools such as limits on interbank
exposures are more effective for constraining household credit growth.
|
Olszak, Roszkowska and Kowalska
(2019)
|
65 countries
|
GMM 2-step Blundell and Bond
approach and random effects method
|
Macroprudential policy instruments
indeed curb the procyclical impact of capital ratios on loan growth rate,
whereby this impact is more pronounced in large banks than in smaller banks.
Of the investigated macroprudential instruments, only borrower-based measures
such as LTV and DTI caps seem to act countercyclically by weakening the positive
impact of capital ratio on bank lending, in particular in crisis periods.
|
Ma (2020)
|
A small open economy
|
A small open economy (SOE) model
with endogenous growth and occasionally binding collateral constraints to analyse
the role of macroprudential policy in the context of a trade-off between
growth and financial stability.
|
Macroprudential policy is shown to
substantially strengthen financial stability (it reduces the frequency and
probability of crises) at the cost of a very small negative effect on average
growth and welfare. In two extensions of the model (one with a growth subsidy
and another one with a direct growth externality), the optimal
macroprudential policy proves to have a more pronounced effect on welfare and
growth. Although macroprudential policy slightly curbs average growth, it is
still desirable to use it, since it enhances financial stability and smooths
consumption.
|
Akinci and Olmstead-Rumsey (2018)
|
57 advanced and emerging economies
|
Estimation of a dynamic panel data
regression model with country fixed effects using the Generalized Method of
Moments (GMM).
|
Macroprudential tightening (by
using macroprudential tools such as LTV limits, DSTI limits, other housing
measures, time-varying capital requirements, provision requirements, consumer
loan limits, and credit growth ceilings) dampens bank credit growth, housing
credit growth, and house price appreciation. Macroprudential policies
targeting the housing sector appear to be more effective at constraining
housing credit growth and house price appreciation, in particular in
economies where bank finance is of greater importance. Counterfactual
simulations indicate that, if the countries had not used any macroprudential
policy measures in the period 2011–2013, the bank credit growth, housing
credit growth and house price appreciation would have been substantially
higher.
|
Meuleman and Vander Vennet (2020)
|
Listed European banks
|
Dynamic panel framework
|
Borrower-oriented tools and
exposure limits are found to reduce the individual bank risk component.
Liquidity measures are found to reduce the systemic linkage of banks in
addition to reducing individual bank risk. Credit growth measures and
exposure limits seem to lead to an increase in systemic risk component for
some banks – possibly because some banks, when trying to observe the rules,
take up riskier activities or similar exposures, thus exacerbating
interconnectedness of the banks in the system. Macroprudential policies seem
to be the most effective for distressed banks, that is banks with a high
ratio of nonperforming loans. The results of the study give some indications
for the optimal design of macroprudential measures.
|
Altunbas, Binici and Gambacorta
(2017)
|
61 advanced and emerging market
economies
|
Baseline empirical regression model
adapted from Altunbas, Gambacorta and Marques-Ibanez (2014); S-GMM estimator
|
The results of the study are
three-fold: Macroprudential policy tools have a substantial effect on bank
risk. Banks with different characteristics do not respond uniformly to
changes in macroprudential policy tools. Small, weakly capitalized banks, and
banks having a high share of wholesale funding respond more strongly to
changes in macroprudential policy tools. Macroprudential policies are more
efficient when employed during a downturn than during a boom.
|
Cizel et al. (2019)
|
40 economies
|
Panel regression; PSM approach to
simulate the effect of a randomized experiment in nonrandom, observed data
|
The authors investigate whether
the implementation of macroprudential policy leads to a substitution of bank
credit with non-bank credit. On the one hand, it could be claimed that the
substitution effect leads to the propagation of new systemic risks, since
when credit shifts away from banks, households and firms continue to accumulate
debt, thus engendering macroeconomic fragility. On the other hand, it could
be asserted that the substitution effect reduces systemic risks, since
non-bank financial institutions are, by and large, less leveraged and with
lower liquidity risks than the banks, and mostly do not have access to public
safety nets, hence are less prone to the moral hazard problem.
|
Dumičić (2018)
|
11 CEE countries
|
Panel regressions using the OLS
method and cross-section SUR panel-corrected standard errors
|
The findings demonstrate that in
the CEE countries, macroprudential policies were more effective in weakening
the flow of credit to households than the flow of credit to the non-financial
corporate sector prior to the global financial crisis with the onset in 2007.
This is predominantly because the non-financial corporate sector also had
access not only to domestic bank credit, but also to non-bank and
cross-border credit. The conclusion of the paper is that some international
cooperation among policymakers is warranted so as to align macroprudential
policies and prevent “regulatory arbitrage”.
|
Source: Authors’ compilation.
Visits refer to users (not robots) and are expressed cumulatively .
Article visits include visits to the article web page and visits to all full text files regarding this article.
To obtain a more realistic insight into the actual visits and reduce the possibility of manipulation (manually or automated) the following records were filtered out: - detected robot visits
- consecutive access to the same page or full text file from the same IP addres
|
|
March, 2022 I/2022 |