1240 Views
545 Downloads |
Education spending, economic development, and the size of government
Article | Year: 2023 | Pages: 285 - 333 | Volume: 47 | Issue: 3 Received: September 29, 2022 | Accepted: June 21, 2023 | Published online: September 4, 2023
|
FULL ARTICLE
FIGURES & DATA
REFERENCES
CROSSMARK POLICY
METRICS
LICENCING
PDF
Variable name
|
Description of the variable
|
Source
|
Dependent variables
|
pse/gdp
|
Public spending on education, total (% of GDP)
|
World Bank EdStats
|
pse/gov
|
Public spending on education, total (% of total government spending)
|
World Bank EdStats
|
Explanatory variables
|
ypc2015
|
GNI per capita country grouping in 2015, 21 OECD countries
|
World Bank (Atlas Method)
|
region
|
Richer (versus poorer) country regions
|
Authors’ compilation
|
poldemoc
|
Political democracy classification: yes; no
|
Freedom House
|
Control variables
|
pop024
|
Population aged 0-24 (% of total population)
|
World Bank EdStats
|
urban
|
Urban population (% of total population)
|
World Bank WDI
|
trade
|
Exports plus imports of goods and services (% of GDP)
|
World Bank WDI
|
hci
|
Human capital index
|
Penn World Table 9.0
|
pop65
|
Population aged 65 and above (% of total population)
|
World Bank WDI
|
military
|
Military expenditure (% of GDP)
|
World Bank WDI
|
fiscbal
|
Fiscal balance (% of GDP)
|
World Bank DPG
|
debt
|
General government gross debt (IMF, % of GDP)
|
World Bank TCdata360
|
Other variables
|
gdppc
|
GDP per capita, PPP (constant 2011 international $)
|
World Bank WDI
|
gini
|
Gini index (World Bank Estimate)
|
World Bank WDI
|
Notes: EdStats refers to the World Bank’s Education Statistics database (World Bank, 2017a). TCdata360 refers to the World Bank’s TCdata360 database (World Bank, 2017b). WDI refers to the World Bank’s World Development Indicators database (World Bank, 2017c). DPG refers to the World Bank’s Development Prospects Group: A Cross-Country Database of Fiscal Space (World Bank, 2017d). The pop024 variable is the sum of pop014 and pop1524 variables from the World Bank EdStats database. Freedom House refers to the Freedom in the World survey data (Freedom House, 2016). See Feenstra, Inklaar and Timmer (2015) for the Penn World Table 9.0.
Dependent variable
|
pse/gdp
|
pse/gov
|
Estimation method
|
LSDV
|
Quantile
|
Robust
|
LSDV
|
Quantile
|
Robust
|
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
1#0. Low income, not democratic
|
-1.551***
|
-1.635***
|
-1.787***
|
-1.885***
|
-1.979***
|
-2.013***
|
3.633***
|
-0.012
|
3.948***
|
-0.162
|
3.387***
|
-0.210
|
(0.254)
|
(0.359)
|
(0.133)
|
(0.260)
|
(0.130)
|
(0.207)
|
(0.436)
|
(0.726)
|
(0.608)
|
(0.696)
|
(0.392)
|
(0.614)
|
1#1. Low income, democratic
|
-1.684***
|
-1.756***
|
-1.757***
|
-1.877***
|
-1.724***
|
-1.759***
|
4.796***
|
1.339*
|
5.135***
|
1.290**
|
4.821***
|
1.467**
|
(0.123)
|
(0.257)
|
(0.127)
|
(0.257)
|
(0.153)
|
(0.216)
|
(0.381)
|
(0.686)
|
(0.366)
|
(0.581)
|
(0.467)
|
(0.643)
|
2#0. Lower middle income, not democratic
|
-1.152***
|
-1.412***
|
-1.170***
|
-1.578***
|
-1.362***
|
-1.611***
|
4.304***
|
1.081*
|
4.231***
|
0.614
|
4.196***
|
0.850*
|
(0.130)
|
(0.220)
|
(0.209)
|
(0.259)
|
(0.116)
|
(0.171)
|
(0.368)
|
(0.600)
|
(0.595)
|
(0.531)
|
(0.353)
|
(0.511)
|
2#1. Lower middle income, democratic
|
-0.454***
|
-0.663***
|
-0.739**
|
-1.126***
|
-0.979***
|
-1.123***
|
4.852***
|
2.421***
|
4.137***
|
1.661***
|
4.224***
|
1.830***
|
(0.158)
|
(0.199)
|
(0.318)
|
(0.287)
|
(0.117)
|
(0.159)
|
(0.369)
|
(0.446)
|
(0.470)
|
(0.419)
|
(0.348)
|
(0.468)
|
3#0. Upper middle income, not democratic
|
-1.090***
|
-1.389***
|
-1.357***
|
-1.669***
|
-1.432***
|
-1.764***
|
2.520***
|
-0.022
|
2.058***
|
-0.131
|
2.317***
|
-0.128
|
(0.155)
|
(0.230)
|
(0.166)
|
(0.177)
|
(0.129)
|
(0.146)
|
(0.455)
|
(0.503)
|
(0.748)
|
(0.371)
|
(0.405)
|
(0.450)
|
3#1. Upper middle income, democratic
|
-0.819***
|
-1.097***
|
-0.797***
|
-1.131***
|
-0.935***
|
-1.133***
|
3.643***
|
1.708***
|
3.556***
|
1.205***
|
3.411***
|
1.347***
|
(0.097)
|
(0.132)
|
(0.106)
|
(0.156)
|
(0.106)
|
(0.127)
|
(0.279)
|
(0.354)
|
(0.331)
|
(0.179)
|
(0.318)
|
(0.374)
|
4#0. High income (non-OECD), not democratic
|
-1.123***
|
-1.987***
|
-1.478***
|
-1.933***
|
-1.329***
|
-2.047***
|
0.987**
|
-2.057***
|
0.034
|
-3.107***
|
0.683
|
-2.852***
|
(0.183)
|
(0.217)
|
(0.152)
|
(0.195)
|
(0.171)
|
(0.189)
|
(0.499)
|
(0.566)
|
(0.751)
|
(0.356)
|
(0.502)
|
(0.543)
|
4#1. High income (non-OECD), democratic
|
-0.814***
|
-0.768***
|
-0.644***
|
-0.654***
|
-0.777***
|
-0.721***
|
0.568**
|
-0.038
|
0.923***
|
0.308
|
0.471
|
-0.099
|
(0.091)
|
(0.101)
|
(0.123)
|
(0.130)
|
(0.106)
|
(0.111)
|
(0.249)
|
(0.254)
|
(0.308)
|
(0.342)
|
(0.333)
|
(0.338)
|
5#0. High income (OECD), not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
5#1. High income (OECD), democratic BASE
|
5.352***
|
3.668***
|
5.226***
|
3.107***
|
5.325***
|
3.449***
|
12.245***
|
4.332***
|
11.973***
|
0.885
|
12.217***
|
2.576***
|
(0.055)
|
(0.312)
|
(0.056)
|
(0.334)
|
(0.073)
|
(0.260)
|
(0.122)
|
(0.831)
|
(0.166)
|
(0.643)
|
(0.214)
|
(0.768)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
pop024
|
|
0.016***
|
|
0.022***
|
|
0.018***
|
|
0.146***
|
|
0.191***
|
|
0.164***
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.015)
|
|
(0.010)
|
|
(0.013)
|
urban
|
|
0.009***
|
|
0.011***
|
|
0.011***
|
|
0.029***
|
|
0.046***
|
|
0.040***
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.007)
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.006)
|
trade
|
|
0.008***
|
|
0.008***
|
|
0.007***
|
|
0.017***
|
|
0.022***
|
|
0.021***
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.060
|
0.100
|
0.074
|
0.107
|
0.123
|
0.190
|
0.141
|
0.198
|
0.092
|
0.146
|
0.136
|
0.226
|
F-value
|
35.86***
|
34.89***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
43.22***
|
48.51***
|
64.55***
|
56.40***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
42.96***
|
54.58***
|
Countries
|
183
|
169
|
183
|
169
|
183
|
169
|
175
|
165
|
175
|
165
|
175
|
165
|
Years
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
Observations
|
2468
|
2288
|
2468
|
2288
|
2468
|
2288
|
2194
|
2069
|
2194
|
2069
|
2194
|
2069
|
Notes: BASE group is high-income (OECD) and democratic countries. A pseudo R-squared is reported for the quantile regression. Not applicable (n/a) means there are no applicable countries for these groups. Standard errors are given in parentheses. Huber/White heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are reported for the LSDV and quantile estimators. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable
|
pse/gdp
|
pse/gov
|
Estimation method
|
LSDV
|
Quantile
|
Robust
|
LSDV
|
Quantile
|
Robust
|
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
0#0. Poorer country regions, not democratic
|
-1.298***
|
-2.031***
|
-1.633***
|
-1.756***
|
-1.681***
|
-1.760***
|
3.880***
|
1.492**
|
4.046***
|
0.726
|
3.757***
|
1.108*
|
(0.147)
|
(0.216)
|
(0.117)
|
(0.234)
|
(0.104)
|
(0.199)
|
(0.305)
|
(0.612)
|
(0.499)
|
(0.764)
|
(0.303)
|
(0.597)
|
0#1. Poorer country regions, democratic
|
-0.804***
|
-1.412***
|
-1.163***
|
-1.235***
|
-1.110***
|
-1.178***
|
5.077***
|
3.321***
|
4.833***
|
2.284***
|
4.923***
|
2.945***
|
(0.104)
|
(0.166)
|
(0.121)
|
(0.180)
|
(0.098)
|
(0.166)
|
(0.233)
|
(0.458)
|
(0.287)
|
(0.496)
|
(0.283)
|
(0.491)
|
1#0. Richer country regions, not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
1#1. Richer country regions, democratic BASE
|
5.169***
|
2.095***
|
5.114***
|
2.047***
|
5.213***
|
2.520***
|
11.944***
|
5.333***
|
11.849***
|
2.093**
|
11.943***
|
3.705***
|
(0.069)
|
(0.375)
|
(0.062)
|
(0.404)
|
(0.074)
|
(0.348)
|
(0.127)
|
(1.193)
|
(0.160)
|
(0.960)
|
(0.212)
|
(1.036)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
pop024
|
|
0.034***
|
|
0.025***
|
|
0.019***
|
|
0.104***
|
|
0.163***
|
|
0.127***
|
|
(0.007)
|
|
(0.007)
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.021)
|
|
(0.019)
|
|
(0.019)
|
urban
|
|
0.016***
|
|
0.022***
|
|
0.020***
|
|
0.029***
|
|
0.044***
|
|
0.037***
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
(0.007)
|
trade
|
|
0.013***
|
|
0.011***
|
|
0.011***
|
|
0.018***
|
|
0.017***
|
|
0.021***
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.057
|
0.167
|
0.090
|
0.170
|
0.154
|
0.313
|
0.195
|
0.222
|
0.140
|
0.171
|
0.189
|
0.247
|
F-value
|
52.61***
|
63.60***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
135.10***
|
125.25***
|
270.00***
|
113.21***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
158.19***
|
84.82***
|
Countries
|
102
|
97
|
102
|
97
|
102
|
97
|
99
|
96
|
99
|
96
|
99
|
96
|
Years
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
Observations
|
1486
|
1382
|
1486
|
1382
|
1486
|
1382
|
1360
|
1299
|
1360
|
|
1360
|
1299
|
Notes: BASE group is richer country regions that are democratic. See the notes for table 2. Standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Wald tests for parameter
equality in table 2
|
|
Robust estimator
|
(A)
|
|
(B)
|
Dependent variable: pse/gdp
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.0125)
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.0125)
|
Test parameter 1#0 = 1#1
|
F(1, 2459)
= 2.19
|
No
|
No
|
F (1, 2276) = 2.33
|
No
|
No
|
p = 0.1388
|
p = 0.1273
|
Test parameter 2#0 = 2#1
|
F(1, 2459) =
8.90
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
F(1, 2276) = 14.79
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.0029
|
p = 0.0001
|
Test parameter 3#0 = 3#1
|
F(1, 2459)
= 14.38
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
F(1, 2276) = 24.17
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.0002
|
p = 0.0000
|
Test parameter 4#0 = 4#1
|
F(1, 2459)
= 10.20
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
F(1, 2276) = 51.44
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.0014
|
p = 0.0000
|
|
Robust estimator
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
Dependent variable: pse/gov
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.0125)
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.0125)
|
Test parameter 1#0 = 1#1
|
F(1, 2185) = 7.33
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
F(1, 2057)
= 11.37
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.0068
|
p = 0.0008
|
Test parameter 2#0 = 2#1
|
F(1, 2185)
= 0.00
|
No
|
No
|
F(1, 2057)
= 6.75
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.9438
|
p = 0.0094
|
Test parameter 3#0 = 3#1
|
F(1, 2185)
= 6.88
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
F(1, 2057)
= 13.88
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.0088
|
p = 0.0002
|
Test parameter 4#0 = 4#1
|
F(1, 2185)
= 0.16
|
No
|
No
|
F(1, 2057)
= 25.58
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.6852
|
p = 0.0000
|
Wald tests for parameter
equality in table 3
|
|
Robust estimator
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
Dependent variable: pse/gdp
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Test parameter 0#0 = 0#1
|
F(1, 1483)
= 33.66
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
F(1, 1376)
= 35.80
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.0000
|
p = 0.0000
|
|
Robust estimator
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
Dependent variable: pse/gov
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Wald Statistic
|
Uncorrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Corrected
Significance
(α = 0.05)
|
Test parameter 0#0 = 0#1
|
F(1, 1357)
= 16.59
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
F(1, 1293)
= 37.70
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
p = 0.0000
|
p = 0.0000
|
Notes: The “#” naming convention accords with that in the respective table of results. Using interaction models with applicable controls, “Yes” means the relevant interaction parameters are statistically significantly different (“No” means not significantly different) from one another for the respective pairwise comparison at the conventional (uncorrected) 5% level of significance or Bonferroni (corrected) level of significance. (A) refers to the model with no controls (unconditional mean differences) and (B) refers to the model with controls (conditional mean differences). Because there is only one pairwise test of parameter equality performed on the estimates from table 3, α (= 0.05) is the same for both the uncorrected and corrected critical level of significance.
Notes: E refers to public spending on education, Y to national income (GDP) and G to total public spending. Subscripts R and P refer to richer and poorer countries, respectively. If Propositions 1 and 2 hold true, then they imply Proposition 3.
Low income
(31)
|
Lower middle income
(52)
|
Upper middle income
(56)
|
High income
(mostly non-OECD) (57)
|
High income
(OECD) (21)
|
Afghanistan
Benin
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Central African Republic
Chad
Comoros
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Eritrea
Ethiopia
Gambia, The
Guinea
Guinea-Bissau
Haiti
Korea, Dem. People’s Rep.
Liberia
Madagascar
Malawi
Mali
Mozambique
Nepal
Niger
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
Somalia
South Sudan
Tanzania
Togo
Uganda
Zimbabwe
|
Armenia
Bangladesh
Bhutan
Bolivia
Cabo Verde
Cambodia
Cameroon
Congo, Rep.
Cote d'Ivoire
Djibouti
Egypt, Arab Rep.
El Salvador
Ghana
Guatemala
Honduras
India
Indonesia
Kenya
Kiribati
Kosovo
Kyrgyz Republic
Lao PDR
Lesotho
Mauritania
Micronesia, Fed. Sts.
Moldova
Mongolia
Morocco
Myanmar
Nicaragua
Nigeria
Pakistan
Papua New Guinea
Philippines
Samoa
Sao Tome and Principe
Solomon Islands
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Swaziland
Syrian Arab Republic
Tajikistan
Timor-Leste
Tonga
Tunisia
Ukraine
Uzbekistan
Vanuatu
Vietnam
West Bank and Gaza
Yemen, Rep.
Zambia
|
Albania
Algeria
American Samoa
Angola
Argentina
Azerbaijan
Belarus
Belize
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Botswana
Brazil
Bulgaria
China
Colombia
Costa Rica
Cuba
Dominica
Dominican Republic
Ecuador
Equatorial Guinea
Fiji
Gabon
Georgia
Grenada
Guyana
Iran, Islamic Rep.
Iraq
Jamaica
Jordan
Kazakhstan
Lebanon
Libya
Macedonia, FYR
Malaysia
Maldives
Marshall Islands
Mauritius
Mexico
Montenegro
Namibia
Palau
Panama
Paraguay
Peru
Romania
Russian Federation
Serbia
South Africa
St. Lucia
St. Vincent and the Grenadines
Suriname
Thailand
Turkey
Turkmenistan
Tuvalu
Venezuela, RB
|
Andorra
Antigua and Barbuda
Aruba
Bahamas, The
Bahrain
Barbados
Bermuda
British Virgin Islands
Brunei Darussalam
Cayman Islands
Channel Islands
Chile
Croatia
Curacao
Cyprus
Czech Republic
Estonia
Faroe Islands
French Polynesia
Gibraltar
Greenland
Guam
Hong Kong SAR, China
Hungary
Iceland
Isle of Man
Israel
Korea, Rep.
Kuwait
Latvia
Liechtenstein
Lithuania
Luxembourg
Macao SAR, China
Malta
Monaco
Nauru
New Caledonia
Northern Mariana Islands
Oman
Poland
Puerto Rico
Qatar
San Marino
Saudi Arabia
Seychelles
Singapore
Sint Maarten (Dutch part)
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
St. Kitts and Nevis
St. Martin (French part)
Trinidad and Tobago
Turks and Caicos Islands
United Arab Emirates
Uruguay
Virgin Islands (U.S.)
|
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Canada
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Ireland
Italy
Japan
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
United Kingdom
United States
|
Notes: Groups are adapted from the World Bank’s Country and Lending Groups for the 2015 calendar year, based on GNI per capita calculated using the World Bank Atlas Method, except for the high-income (OECD) group, which includes the 21 countries comprising the “core” OECD countries that have been categorised as OECD for the entire study period, from 1989 to 2015 (i.e., excluding Chile, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Iceland, Israel, Korea, Latvia, Luxembourg, Mexico, Poland, Slovak Republic, Slovenia and Turkey, which are mostly included in the second high-income group). Numbers in parentheses show the total number of countries in each group. The historical classification is available from: https://datahelpdesk.worldbank.org/knowledgebase/articles/906519-world-bank-country-and-lending-groups. Source: Adapted from the World Bank’s historical classification.
Poorer country regions
|
Central Africa (8)
|
Central America (8)
|
East Africa (12)
|
South America (12)
|
South Asia (8)
|
Cameroon
Central African Republic
Chad
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Congo, Rep.
Equatorial Guinea
Gabon
Sao Tome and Principe
|
Belize
Costa Rica
El Salvador
Guatemala
Honduras
Mexico
Nicaragua
Panama
|
Burundi
Comoros
Djibouti
Eritrea
Ethiopia
Kenya
Rwanda
Somalia
South Sudan
Sudan
Tanzania
Uganda
|
Argentina
Bolivia
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Ecuador
Guyana
Paraguay
Peru
Suriname
Uruguay
Venezuela, RB
|
Afghanistan
Bangladesh
Bhutan
India
Maldives
Nepal
Pakistan
Sri Lanka
|
Southeast Asia (11)
|
Southern Africa (13)
|
West Africa (16)
|
|
|
Brunei Darussalam
Cambodia
Indonesia
Lao PDR
Malaysia
Myanmar
Philippines
Singapore
Thailand
Timor-Leste
Vietnam
|
Angola
Botswana
Lesotho
Madagascar
Malawi
Mauritius
Mozambique
Namibia
Seychelles
South Africa
Swaziland
Zambia
Zimbabwe
|
Benin
Burkina Faso
Cabo Verde
Cote d’Ivoire
Gambia, The
Ghana
Guinea
Guinea-Bissau
Liberia
Mali
Mauritania
Niger
Nigeria
Senegal
Sierra Leone
Togo
|
|
|
Richer country regions
|
North America (3)
|
Nordic Countries (5)
|
Western Europe (22)
|
|
|
Bermuda
Canada
United States
|
Denmark
Finland
Iceland
Norway
Sweden
|
Andorra
Austria
Belgium
Channel Islands
Faroe Islands
France
Germany
Gibraltar
Greece
Greenland
Ireland
Isle of Man
Italy
Liechtenstein
Luxembourg
Monaco
Netherlands
Portugal
San Marino
Spain
Switzerland
United Kingdom
|
|
|
Notes: The numbers in parentheses show the total number of countries in each sub-group of the respective country regions. For the poorer country regions, Equatorial Guinea, Chile, Uruguay, Brunei Darussalam, Singapore and Seychelles (the countries in bold) are excluded because they are classified as high-income (non-OECD) countries for most or all of the time period under investigation (from 1989 to 2015). Source: Authors’ compilation.
Variable name
|
Data coverage
|
N
|
Countries
|
Years
|
Mean
|
Std dev.
|
Minimum
|
Maximum
|
pse/gdp
|
1989-2015
|
2551
|
193
|
13.2
|
4.505
|
2.007
|
0.781
|
44.334
|
pse/gov
|
1989-2015
|
2255
|
181
|
12.5
|
14.849
|
5.036
|
2.563
|
47.279
|
ypc2015
|
1989-2015
|
5859
|
217
|
27.0
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
region
|
1989-2015
|
3024
|
112
|
27.0
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
poldemoc
|
1989-2015
|
5105
|
193
|
26.5
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
pop024
|
1990-2015
|
4714
|
184
|
25.6
|
49.977
|
13.687
|
20.160
|
73.288
|
urban
|
1989-2015
|
5799
|
215
|
27.0
|
55.788
|
24.901
|
5.342
|
100.000
|
trade
|
1989-2015
|
4785
|
193
|
24.8
|
86.996
|
52.290
|
0.021
|
531.737
|
hci
|
1989-2014
|
3703
|
143
|
25.9
|
2.342
|
0.694
|
1.028
|
3.734
|
pop65
|
1989-2015
|
5234
|
195
|
26.8
|
7.073
|
4.814
|
0.697
|
26.342
|
military
|
1989-2015
|
3870
|
166
|
23.3
|
2.433
|
3.210
|
0
|
117.388
|
fiscbal
|
1990-2015
|
4184
|
191
|
21.9
|
-2.299
|
13.715
|
-505.442
|
122.188
|
debt
|
1989-2015
|
3796
|
186
|
20.4
|
57.015
|
49.714
|
0
|
789.833
|
gini
|
1989-2014
|
1188
|
155
|
7.7
|
39.875
|
9.871
|
16.23
|
65.76
|
gdppc
|
1990-2015
|
4803
|
195
|
24.6
|
15111
|
18507
|
247
|
137164
|
Notes: Years refers to the average number of years (time-series observations) for each country. Std. dev. refers to the overall standard deviation. Two changes were made to the original data for the pse/gdp variable. The zero observation for Turkey in 1998 was deleted (because there were no other 0% values in the dataset; nil or negligible appeared in the original UNESCO source data for this observation) and the observation for Tuvalu in 1997 (3730833.5%) was deleted as an obvious mistake; the extreme value for this observation also appeared in the original UNESCO source data. It was subsequently noted that this observation was deleted from the World Bank’s Education Statistics (EdStats) data as of the update dated 21 May 2018. Descriptive results are not reported for ypc2015 (21 OECD countries), region and poldemoc because these are sets of binary variables used to characterise broad political and economic categories.
Dependent variable: pse/gdp
|
LSDV
|
LSDV
(One-way; Country)
|
LSDV
(One-way; Year)
|
LSDV
(Two-way)
|
Newey-West
|
Driscoll-Kraay
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
1#0. Low income, not democratic
|
-1.551***
|
-1.635***
|
-1.551***
|
-1.635*
|
-1.551***
|
-1.635***
|
-1.551***
|
-1.635*
|
-1.551***
|
-1.635***
|
-1.551***
|
-1.635***
|
(0.254)
|
(0.359)
|
(0.544)
|
(0.911)
|
(0.265)
|
(0.394)
|
(0.549)
|
(0.926)
|
(0.311)
|
(0.486)
|
(0.294)
|
(0.531)
|
1#1. Low income, democratic
|
-1.684***
|
-1.756***
|
-1.684***
|
-1.756**
|
-1.684***
|
-1.756***
|
-1.684***
|
-1.756**
|
-1.684***
|
-1.756***
|
-1.684***
|
-1.756***
|
(0.123)
|
(0.257)
|
(0.330)
|
(0.774)
|
(0.129)
|
(0.255)
|
(0.332)
|
(0.773)
|
(0.178)
|
(0.389)
|
(0.185)
|
(0.371)
|
2#0. Lower middle income, not democratic
|
-1.152***
|
-1.412***
|
-1.152***
|
-1.412**
|
-1.152***
|
-1.412***
|
-1.152***
|
-1.412**
|
-1.152***
|
-1.412***
|
-1.152***
|
-1.412***
|
(0.130)
|
(0.220)
|
(0.406)
|
(0.688)
|
(0.108)
|
(0.197)
|
(0.399)
|
(0.681)
|
(0.196)
|
(0.338)
|
(0.152)
|
(0.290)
|
2#1. Lower middle income, democratic
|
-0.454***
|
-0.663***
|
-0.454
|
-0.663
|
-0.454***
|
-0.663***
|
-0.454
|
-0.663
|
-0.454*
|
-0.663**
|
-0.454***
|
-0.663***
|
(0.158)
|
(0.199)
|
(0.484)
|
(0.627)
|
(0.108)
|
(0.131)
|
(0.470)
|
(0.609)
|
(0.235)
|
(0.305)
|
(0.162)
|
(0.169)
|
3#0. Upper middle income, not democratic
|
-1.090***
|
-1.389***
|
-1.090**
|
-1.389*
|
-1.090***
|
-1.389***
|
-1.090**
|
-1.389*
|
-1.090***
|
-1.389***
|
-1.090***
|
-1.389***
|
(0.155)
|
(0.230)
|
(0.534)
|
(0.801)
|
(0.131)
|
(0.140)
|
(0.527)
|
(0.780)
|
(0.244)
|
(0.369)
|
(0.195)
|
(0.193)
|
3#1. Upper middle income, democratic
|
-0.819***
|
-1.097***
|
-0.819***
|
-1.097**
|
-0.819***
|
-1.097***
|
-0.819***
|
-1.097***
|
-0.819***
|
-1.097***
|
-0.819***
|
-1.097***
|
(0.097)
|
(0.132)
|
(0.295)
|
(0.423)
|
(0.085)
|
(0.119)
|
(0.292)
|
(0.419)
|
(0.141)
|
(0.203)
|
(0.092)
|
(0.159)
|
4#0. High income (non-OECD), not democratic
|
-1.123***
|
-1.987***
|
-1.123**
|
-1.987***
|
-1.123***
|
-1.987***
|
-1.123**
|
-1.987***
|
-1.123***
|
-1.987***
|
-1.123***
|
-1.987***
|
(0.183)
|
(0.217)
|
(0.514)
|
(0.702)
|
(0.197)
|
(0.192)
|
(0.519)
|
(0.695)
|
(0.249)
|
(0.332)
|
(0.273)
|
(0.259)
|
4#1. High income (non-OECD), democratic
|
-0.814***
|
-0.768***
|
-0.814**
|
-0.768**
|
-0.814***
|
-0.768***
|
-0.814**
|
-0.768**
|
-0.814***
|
-0.768***
|
-0.814***
|
-0.768***
|
(0.091)
|
(0.101)
|
(0.338)
|
(0.357)
|
(0.049)
|
(0.064)
|
(0.329)
|
(0.348)
|
(0.144)
|
(0.156)
|
(0.059)
|
(0.085)
|
5#0. High income (OECD), not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
5#1. High income (OECD), democratic BASE
|
5.352***
|
3.668***
|
5.352***
|
3.668***
|
5.352***
|
3.668***
|
5.352***
|
3.668***
|
5.352***
|
3.668***
|
5.352***
|
3.668***
|
(0.055)
|
(0.312)
|
(0.225)
|
(0.945)
|
(0.058)
|
(0.171)
|
(0.226)
|
(0.908)
|
(0.089)
|
(0.467)
|
(0.083)
|
(0.200)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
pop024
|
|
0.016***
|
|
0.016
|
|
0.016***
|
|
0.016
|
|
0.016*
|
|
0.016**
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.018)
|
|
(0.005)
|
|
(0.018)
|
|
(0.009)
|
|
(0.007)
|
urban
|
|
0.009***
|
|
0.009
|
|
0.009***
|
|
0.009
|
|
0.009**
|
|
0.009***
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
(0.007)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.002)
|
trade
|
|
0.008***
|
|
0.008**
|
|
0.008***
|
|
0.008**
|
|
0.008***
|
|
0.008***
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.001)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.060
|
0.100
|
0.060
|
0.100
|
0.060
|
0.100
|
0.060
|
0.100
|
0.060
|
0.100
|
0.060
|
0.100
|
F-value
|
35.86***
|
34.89***
|
3.78***
|
3.79***
|
78.63***
|
120.42***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
15.83***
|
15.72***
|
60.00***
|
387.40***
|
Countries
|
183
|
169
|
183
|
169
|
183
|
169
|
183
|
169
|
183
|
169
|
183
|
169
|
Years
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
Observations
|
2468
|
2288
|
2468
|
2288
|
2468
|
2288
|
2468
|
2288
|
2468
|
2288
|
2468
|
2288
|
Notes: BASE group is high-income (OECD) and democratic countries. Three controls are used: youth population (pop024); urban population (urban) and trade (trade). A pseudo R-squared is reported for the quantile regression. Not applicable (n/a) means there are no applicable countries for these groups. The LSDV estimator using Huber/White heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors is reproduced from table 2 for ease of comparison. The various other standard error estimates for LSDV use one-way (country or year) and two-way (country and year) cluster-robust standard errors. The Newey-West and Driscoll-Kraay estimators use their own covariance matrix corrections to compute heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent (HAC), and cross-sectional or spatial correlation consistent standard errors under different data-generating assumptions, respectively. The various standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gov
|
LSDV
|
LSDV
(One-way; Country)
|
LSDV
(One-way; Year)
|
LSDV
(Two-way)
|
Newey-West
|
Driscoll-Kraay
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
1#0. Low income, not democratic
|
3.633***
|
-0.012
|
3.633***
|
-0.012
|
3.633***
|
-0.012
|
3.633***
|
-0.012
|
3.633***
|
-0.012
|
3.633***
|
-0.012
|
(0.436)
|
(0.726)
|
(1.208)
|
(2.003)
|
(0.292)
|
(0.682)
|
(1.163)
|
(1.988)
|
(0.644)
|
(1.069)
|
(0.314)
|
(0.984)
|
1#1. Low income, democratic
|
4.796***
|
1.339*
|
4.796***
|
1.339
|
4.796***
|
1.339*
|
4.796***
|
1.339
|
4.796***
|
1.339
|
4.796***
|
1.339
|
(0.381)
|
(0.686)
|
(0.832)
|
(1.748)
|
(0.310)
|
(0.754)
|
(0.802)
|
(1.776)
|
(0.500)
|
(0.966)
|
(0.451)
|
(1.092)
|
2#0. Lower middle income, not democratic
|
4.304***
|
1.081*
|
4.304***
|
1.081
|
4.304***
|
1.081*
|
4.304***
|
1.081
|
4.304***
|
1.081
|
4.304***
|
1.081
|
(0.368)
|
(0.600)
|
(1.148)
|
(1.791)
|
(0.348)
|
(0.563)
|
(1.142)
|
(1.779)
|
(0.555)
|
(0.899)
|
(0.468)
|
(0.803)
|
2#1. Lower middle income, democratic
|
4.852***
|
2.421***
|
4.852***
|
2.421*
|
4.852***
|
2.421***
|
4.852***
|
2.421**
|
4.852***
|
2.421***
|
4.852***
|
2.421***
|
(0.369)
|
(0.446)
|
(1.009)
|
(1.236)
|
(0.214)
|
(0.390)
|
(0.963)
|
(1.217)
|
(0.548)
|
(0.639)
|
(0.219)
|
(0.440)
|
3#0. Upper middle income, not democratic
|
2.520***
|
-0.022
|
2.520*
|
-0.022
|
2.520***
|
-0.022
|
2.520*
|
-0.022
|
2.520***
|
-0.022
|
2.520***
|
-0.022
|
(0.455)
|
(0.503)
|
(1.380)
|
(1.502)
|
(0.461)
|
(0.378)
|
(1.382)
|
(1.465)
|
(0.663)
|
(0.749)
|
(0.668)
|
(0.547)
|
3#1. Upper middle income, democratic
|
3.643***
|
1.708***
|
3.643***
|
1.708
|
3.643***
|
1.708***
|
3.643***
|
1.708
|
3.643***
|
1.708***
|
3.643***
|
1.708**
|
(0.279)
|
(0.354)
|
(0.862)
|
(1.053)
|
(0.230)
|
(0.415)
|
(0.847)
|
(1.076)
|
(0.409)
|
(0.524)
|
(0.280)
|
(0.617)
|
4#0. High income (non-OECD), not democratic
|
0.987**
|
-2.057***
|
0.987
|
-2.057
|
0.987**
|
-2.057***
|
0.987
|
-2.057
|
0.987
|
-2.057**
|
0.987*
|
-2.057***
|
(0.499)
|
(0.566)
|
(1.699)
|
(1.648)
|
(0.378)
|
(0.407)
|
(1.668)
|
(1.600)
|
(0.770)
|
(0.830)
|
(0.516)
|
(0.339)
|
4#1. High income (non-OECD), democratic
|
0.568**
|
-0.038
|
0.568
|
-0.038
|
0.568***
|
-0.038
|
0.568
|
-0.038
|
0.568
|
-0.038
|
0.568**
|
-0.038
|
(0.249)
|
(0.254)
|
(0.834)
|
(0.815)
|
(0.188)
|
(0.211)
|
(0.818)
|
(0.803)
|
(0.372)
|
(0.379)
|
(0.260)
|
(0.284)
|
5#0. High income (OECD), not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
5#1. High income (OECD), democratic BASE
|
12.245***
|
4.332***
|
12.245***
|
4.332**
|
12.245***
|
4.332***
|
12.245***
|
4.332**
|
12.245***
|
4.332***
|
12.245***
|
4.332***
|
(0.122)
|
(0.831)
|
(0.500)
|
(2.156)
|
(0.088)
|
(0.602)
|
(0.493)
|
(2.079)
|
(0.196)
|
(1.172)
|
(0.128)
|
(0.621)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
pop024
|
|
0.146***
|
|
0.146***
|
|
0.146***
|
|
0.146***
|
|
0.146***
|
|
0.146***
|
|
(0.015)
|
|
(0.038)
|
|
(0.013)
|
|
(0.038)
|
|
(0.021)
|
|
(0.017)
|
urban
|
|
0.029***
|
|
0.029
|
|
0.029***
|
|
0.029
|
|
0.029***
|
|
0.029***
|
|
(0.007)
|
|
(0.020)
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.020)
|
|
(0.010)
|
|
(0.009)
|
trade
|
|
0.017***
|
|
0.017***
|
|
0.017***
|
|
0.017***
|
|
0.017***
|
|
0.017***
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.006)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.141
|
0.198
|
0.141
|
0.198
|
0.141
|
0.198
|
0.141
|
0.198
|
0.141
|
0.198
|
0.141
|
0.198
|
F-value
|
64.55***
|
56.40***
|
7.16***
|
8.08***
|
234.33***
|
201.25***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
29.30***
|
26.94***
|
315.69***
|
476.80***
|
Countries
|
175
|
165
|
175
|
165
|
175
|
165
|
175
|
165
|
175
|
165
|
175
|
165
|
Years
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
Observations
|
2194
|
2069
|
2194
|
2069
|
2194
|
2069
|
2194
|
2069
|
2194
|
2069
|
2194
|
2069
|
Notes: BASE group is high-income (OECD) and democratic countries. The model uses three controls: youth population (pop024); urban population (urban) and trade (trade). See the notes for table A4. The various standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gdp
|
LSDV
|
LSDV
(One-way; Country)
|
LSDV
(One-way; Year)
|
LSDV
(Two-way)
|
Newey-West
|
Driscoll-Kraay
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
0#0. Poorer country regions, not democratic
|
-1.298***
|
-2.031***
|
-1.298***
|
-2.031***
|
-1.298***
|
-2.031***
|
-1.298***
|
-2.031***
|
-1.298***
|
-2.031***
|
-1.298***
|
-2.031***
|
(0.147)
|
(0.216)
|
(0.396)
|
(0.582)
|
(0.128)
|
(0.168)
|
(0.389)
|
(0.566)
|
(0.199)
|
(0.315)
|
(0.152)
|
(0.218)
|
0#1. Poorer country regions, democratic
|
-0.804***
|
-1.412***
|
-0.804**
|
-1.412***
|
-0.804***
|
-1.412***
|
-0.804**
|
-1.412***
|
-0.804***
|
-1.412***
|
-0.804***
|
-1.412***
|
(0.104)
|
(0.166)
|
(0.343)
|
(0.467)
|
(0.081)
|
(0.135)
|
(0.336)
|
(0.457)
|
(0.158)
|
(0.239)
|
(0.110)
|
(0.162)
|
1#0. Richer country regions, not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
1#1. Richer country regions, democratic BASE
|
5.169***
|
2.095***
|
5.169***
|
2.095**
|
5.169***
|
2.095***
|
5.169***
|
2.095**
|
5.169***
|
2.095***
|
5.169***
|
2.095***
|
(0.069)
|
(0.375)
|
(0.264)
|
(0.989)
|
(0.052)
|
(0.255)
|
(0.260)
|
(0.950)
|
(0.110)
|
(0.534)
|
(0.064)
|
(0.319)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
pop024
|
|
0.034***
|
|
0.034**
|
|
0.034***
|
|
0.034**
|
|
0.034***
|
|
0.034***
|
|
(0.007)
|
|
(0.017)
|
|
(0.005)
|
|
(0.016)
|
|
(0.010)
|
|
(0.005)
|
urban
|
|
0.016***
|
|
0.016**
|
|
0.016***
|
|
0.016**
|
|
0.016***
|
|
0.016***
|
|
(0.003)
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.002)
|
trade
|
|
0.013***
|
|
0.013***
|
|
0.013***
|
|
0.013***
|
|
0.013***
|
|
0.013***
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.002)
|
|
(0.002)
|
R-squared
|
0.057
|
0.167
|
0.057
|
0.167
|
0.057
|
0.167
|
0.057
|
0.167
|
0.057
|
0.167
|
0.057
|
0.167
|
F-value
|
52.61***
|
63.60***
|
5.45***
|
6.80***
|
148.23***
|
109.08***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
24.89***
|
31.33***
|
161.84***
|
103.56***
|
Countries
|
102
|
97
|
102
|
97
|
102
|
97
|
102
|
97
|
102
|
97
|
102
|
97
|
Years
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
Observations
|
1486
|
1382
|
1486
|
1382
|
1486
|
1382
|
1486
|
1382
|
1486
|
1382
|
1486
|
1382
|
Notes: BASE group is richer country regions that are democratic. The model uses three controls: youth population (pop024); urban population (urban) and trade (trade). See the notes for table A4. The various standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels are as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gov
|
LSDV
|
LSDV
(One-way; Country)
|
LSDV
(One-way; Year)
|
LSDV
(Two-way)
|
Newey-West
|
Driscoll-Kraay
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
(A)
|
(B)
|
0#0. Poorer country regions, not democratic
|
3.880***
|
1.492**
|
3.880***
|
1.492
|
3.880***
|
1.492***
|
3.880***
|
1.492
|
3.880***
|
1.492*
|
3.880***
|
1.492***
|
(0.305)
|
(0.612)
|
(0.909)
|
(1.609)
|
(0.229)
|
(0.360)
|
(0.887)
|
(1.531)
|
(0.452)
|
(0.892)
|
(0.210)
|
(0.466)
|
0#1. Poorer country regions, democratic
|
5.077***
|
3.321***
|
5.077***
|
3.321**
|
5.077***
|
3.321***
|
5.077***
|
3.321**
|
5.077***
|
3.321***
|
5.077***
|
3.321***
|
(0.233)
|
(0.458)
|
(0.711)
|
(1.397)
|
(0.141)
|
(0.236)
|
(0.686)
|
(1.341)
|
(0.345)
|
(0.684)
|
(0.157)
|
(0.301)
|
1#0. Richer country regions, not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
1#1. Richer country regions, democratic BASE
|
11.944***
|
5.333***
|
11.944***
|
5.333
|
11.944***
|
5.333***
|
11.944***
|
5.333*
|
11.944***
|
5.333***
|
11.944***
|
5.333***
|
(0.127)
|
(1.193)
|
(0.506)
|
(3.265)
|
(0.116)
|
(0.952)
|
(0.504)
|
(3.185)
|
(0.203)
|
(1.719)
|
(0.176)
|
(1.039)
|
pop024
|
|
0.104***
|
|
0.104*
|
|
0.104***
|
|
0.104*
|
|
0.104***
|
|
0.104***
|
|
(0.021)
|
|
(0.059)
|
|
(0.013)
|
|
(0.056)
|
|
(0.030)
|
|
(0.015)
|
urban
|
|
0.029***
|
|
0.029
|
|
0.029***
|
|
0.029
|
|
0.029**
|
|
0.029***
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
(0.023)
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
(0.023)
|
|
(0.012)
|
|
(0.009)
|
trade
|
|
0.018***
|
|
0.018**
|
|
0.018***
|
|
0.018**
|
|
0.018***
|
|
0.018***
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.009)
|
|
(0.004)
|
|
(0.009)
|
|
(0.005)
|
|
(0.004)
|
R-squared
|
0.195
|
0.222
|
0.195
|
0.222
|
0.195
|
0.222
|
0.195
|
0.222
|
0.195
|
0.222
|
0.195
|
0.222
|
F-value
|
270.00***
|
113.21***
|
25.86***
|
13.06***
|
723.40***
|
323.35***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
118.36***
|
51.83***
|
611.34***
|
290.39***
|
Countries
|
99
|
96
|
99
|
96
|
99
|
96
|
99
|
96
|
99
|
96
|
99
|
96
|
Years
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
27
|
26
|
Observations
|
1360
|
1299
|
1360
|
1299
|
1360
|
1299
|
1360
|
1299
|
1360
|
1299
|
1360
|
1299
|
Notes: BASE group is richer country regions that are democratic. The model uses three controls: youth population (pop024); urban population (urban) and trade (trade). See the notes for table A4. The various standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gdp
|
I
|
II
|
III
|
IV
|
V
|
VI
|
VII
|
VIII
|
IX
|
X
|
XI
|
XII
|
0#0. Poorer country regions, not democratic
|
-2.031***
|
-2.183***
|
-1.764***
|
-1.866***
|
-0.991***
|
-1.072***
|
-0.568*
|
-0.692*
|
-0.800***
|
-1.146***
|
-0.906***
|
-1.163***
|
(0.216)
|
(0.242)
|
(0.224)
|
(0.258)
|
(0.275)
|
(0.365)
|
(0.296)
|
(0.383)
|
(0.268)
|
(0.293)
|
(0.279)
|
(0.307)
|
0#1. Poorer country regions, democratic
|
-1.412***
|
-1.543***
|
-1.379***
|
-1.448***
|
-0.578**
|
-0.631**
|
-0.028
|
-0.102
|
-0.021
|
-0.277
|
-0.042
|
-0.241
|
(0.166)
|
(0.155)
|
(0.176)
|
(0.167)
|
(0.237)
|
(0.288)
|
(0.258)
|
(0.315)
|
(0.257)
|
(0.279)
|
(0.265)
|
(0.288)
|
1#0. Richer country regions, not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
1#1. Richer country regions, democratic BASE
|
2.095***
|
1.504***
|
-1.863**
|
-2.243***
|
-5.403***
|
-5.626***
|
-7.503***
|
-7.711***
|
-6.685***
|
-6.649***
|
-6.539***
|
-6.743***
|
(0.375)
|
(0.518)
|
(0.760)
|
(0.790)
|
(1.427)
|
(1.549)
|
(1.550)
|
(1.713)
|
(1.241)
|
(1.295)
|
(1.297)
|
(1.370)
|
R-squared
|
0.167
|
0.187
|
0.201
|
0.223
|
0.208
|
0.229
|
0.223
|
0.245
|
0.353
|
0.375
|
0.365
|
0.384
|
F-value
|
63.60***
|
15.33***
|
103.09***
|
23.20***
|
91.08***
|
22.81***
|
80.33***
|
21.89***
|
69.88***
|
21.30***
|
60.49***
|
19.72***
|
Countries
|
97
|
97
|
86
|
86
|
86
|
86
|
85
|
85
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
Years
|
26
|
26
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
Year fixed effects
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
Covariates (controls)
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Number of control variables
|
3
|
3
|
4
|
4
|
5
|
5
|
6
|
6
|
7
|
7
|
8
|
8
|
Are patterns confounded?
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Partially
|
Partially
|
Partially
|
Partially
|
Partially
|
Partially
|
Observations
|
1382
|
1382
|
1256
|
1256
|
1256
|
1256
|
1174
|
1174
|
1101
|
1101
|
1030
|
1030
|
Notes: BASE group is richer country regions that are democratic. All models use a LSDV estimator and robust standard errors. I and II use homogeneous slopes and three controls (pop024, urban and trade). III and IV use homogeneous slopes and four controls (pop024, urban, trade and hci). V and VI use homogeneous slopes and five controls (pop024, urban, trade, hci and pop65). VII and VIII use homogeneous slopes and six controls (pop024, urban, trade, hci, pop65 and military). IX and X use homogeneous slopes and seven controls (pop024, urban, trade, hci, pop65, military and fiscbal). XI and XII use homogeneous slopes and eight controls (pop024, urban, trade, hci, pop65, military, fiscbal and debt). See table 1 for a description of each control variable used. Time (year) dummies are used in even-numbered specifications (II, IV, VI, VIII, X and XII). The estimates for the various controls and year fixed effects are excluded to save space. Huber-White heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gov
|
I
|
II
|
III
|
IV
|
V
|
VI
|
VII
|
VIII
|
IX
|
X
|
XI
|
XII
|
0#0. Poorer country regions, not democratic
|
1.492**
|
0.985
|
1.296**
|
0.737
|
1.358**
|
0.499
|
2.207***
|
1.514**
|
1.962***
|
1.269*
|
1.803***
|
1.668**
|
(0.612)
|
(0.664)
|
(0.644)
|
(0.700)
|
(0.637)
|
(0.718)
|
(0.661)
|
(0.755)
|
(0.656)
|
(0.749)
|
(0.667)
|
(0.756)
|
0#1. Poorer country regions, democratic
|
3.321***
|
2.799***
|
2.970***
|
2.451***
|
3.035***
|
2.204***
|
3.784***
|
3.186***
|
3.717***
|
3.162***
|
3.561***
|
3.391***
|
(0.458)
|
(0.499)
|
(0.481)
|
(0.530)
|
(0.518)
|
(0.596)
|
(0.548)
|
(0.628)
|
(0.539)
|
(0.621)
|
(0.552)
|
(0.630)
|
1#0. Richer country regions, not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
1#1. Richer country regions, democratic BASE
|
5.333***
|
3.726***
|
-3.448**
|
-4.803***
|
-3.737
|
-3.794
|
-4.396
|
-4.194
|
-1.745
|
-1.109
|
-1.285
|
-1.221
|
(1.193)
|
(1.443)
|
(1.686)
|
(1.810)
|
(2.738)
|
(2.805)
|
(2.840)
|
(2.923)
|
(2.867)
|
(2.948)
|
(2.897)
|
(2.955)
|
R-squared
|
0.222
|
0.237
|
0.296
|
0.311
|
0.296
|
0.311
|
0.331
|
0.343
|
0.347
|
0.360
|
0.415
|
0.423
|
F-value
|
113.21***
|
20.02***
|
110.62***
|
23.58***
|
100.86***
|
24.23***
|
91.63***
|
23.86***
|
92.91***
|
27.10***
|
96.81***
|
31.64***
|
Countries
|
96
|
96
|
85
|
85
|
85
|
85
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
Years
|
26
|
26
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year fixed effects
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
Covariates (controls)
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Number of control variables
|
3
|
3
|
4
|
4
|
5
|
5
|
6
|
6
|
7
|
7
|
8
|
8
|
Are patterns confounded?
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Observations
|
1299
|
1299
|
1175
|
1175
|
1175
|
1175
|
1099
|
1099
|
1091
|
1091
|
1024
|
1024
|
Notes: BASE group is richer country regions that are democratic. All models use a LSDV estimator and robust standard errors. See the notes for table A8. Huber-White heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels are as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gdp
|
I
|
II
|
III
|
IV
|
V
|
VI
|
VII
|
VIII
|
IX
|
X
|
XI
|
XII
|
0#0. Poorer country regions, not democratic
|
-1.760***
|
-2.022***
|
-1.489***
|
-1.729***
|
-1.240***
|
-1.615***
|
-0.926***
|
-1.311***
|
-0.930***
|
-1.332***
|
-1.077***
|
-1.418***
|
(0.199)
|
(0.206)
|
(0.199)
|
(0.208)
|
(0.260)
|
(0.275)
|
(0.274)
|
(0.291)
|
(0.279)
|
(0.297)
|
(0.274)
|
(0.297)
|
0#1. Poorer country regions, democratic
|
-1.178***
|
-1.403***
|
-1.111***
|
-1.310***
|
-0.844***
|
-1.188***
|
-0.455*
|
-0.785***
|
-0.424*
|
-0.734***
|
-0.522**
|
-0.797***
|
(0.166)
|
(0.172)
|
(0.165)
|
(0.172)
|
(0.239)
|
(0.252)
|
(0.253)
|
(0.267)
|
(0.256)
|
(0.271)
|
(0.250)
|
(0.268)
|
1#0. Richer country regions, not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
1#1. Richer country regions, democratic BASE
|
2.520***
|
1.764***
|
0.251
|
-0.321
|
-1.013
|
-0.848
|
-2.635***
|
-2.416**
|
-3.139***
|
-2.862***
|
-2.688***
|
-2.624**
|
(0.348)
|
(0.425)
|
(0.520)
|
(0.566)
|
(0.924)
|
(0.951)
|
(0.965)
|
(0.998)
|
(1.002)
|
(1.041)
|
(0.988)
|
(1.053)
|
R-squared
|
0.313
|
0.335
|
0.331
|
0.351
|
0.333
|
0.351
|
0.338
|
0.357
|
0.340
|
0.363
|
0.373
|
0.392
|
F-value
|
125.25***
|
22.67***
|
103.17***
|
22.06***
|
88.81***
|
21.32***
|
74.25***
|
19.81***
|
62.34***
|
18.39***
|
60.71***
|
18.87***
|
Countries
|
97
|
97
|
86
|
86
|
86
|
86
|
85
|
85
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
Years
|
26
|
26
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year fixed effects
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
Covariates (controls)
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Number of control variables
|
3
|
3
|
4
|
4
|
5
|
5
|
6
|
6
|
7
|
7
|
8
|
8
|
Are the patterns confounded?
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Observations
|
1382
|
1382
|
1256
|
1256
|
1256
|
1256
|
1174
|
1174
|
1101
|
1101
|
1030
|
1030
|
Notes: BASE group is richer country regions that are democratic. All models use a robust estimator. See the notes for table A8. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gov
|
I
|
II
|
III
|
IV
|
V
|
VI
|
VII
|
VIII
|
IX
|
X
|
XI
|
XII
|
0#0. Poorer country regions, not democratic
|
1.108*
|
0.522
|
1.000*
|
0.310
|
1.122
|
0.172
|
1.972**
|
1.255
|
1.798**
|
1.077
|
1.614**
|
1.315*
|
(0.597)
|
(0.626)
|
(0.588)
|
(0.617)
|
(0.761)
|
(0.806)
|
(0.771)
|
(0.829)
|
(0.751)
|
(0.804)
|
(0.702)
|
(0.767)
|
0#1. Poorer country regions, democratic
|
2.945***
|
2.335***
|
2.626***
|
1.919***
|
2.760***
|
1.777**
|
3.292***
|
2.617***
|
3.268***
|
2.608***
|
3.037***
|
2.724***
|
(0.491)
|
(0.517)
|
(0.479)
|
(0.503)
|
(0.697)
|
(0.737)
|
(0.709)
|
(0.757)
|
(0.690)
|
(0.734)
|
(0.642)
|
(0.694)
|
1#0. Richer country regions, not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
1#1. Richer country regions, democratic BASE
|
3.705***
|
1.652
|
-4.570***
|
-6.683***
|
-5.296*
|
-5.963**
|
-5.074*
|
-5.589**
|
-2.121
|
-2.119
|
-1.306
|
-1.495
|
(1.036)
|
(1.400)
|
(1.533)
|
(1.748)
|
(2.708)
|
(2.810)
|
(2.701)
|
(2.838)
|
(2.692)
|
(2.821)
|
(2.531)
|
(2.719)
|
R-squared
|
0.247
|
0.264
|
0.328
|
0.348
|
0.328
|
0.347
|
0.373
|
0.386
|
0.402
|
0.421
|
0.483
|
0.492
|
F-value
|
84.82***
|
15.18***
|
94.92***
|
20.35***
|
81.47***
|
19.61***
|
81.11***
|
20.98***
|
80.84***
|
23.30***
|
94.69***
|
28.19***
|
Countries
|
96
|
96
|
85
|
85
|
85
|
85
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
84
|
Years
|
26
|
26
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
25
|
Year fixed effects
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
No
|
Yes
|
Covariates (controls)
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Number of control variables
|
3
|
3
|
4
|
4
|
5
|
5
|
6
|
6
|
7
|
7
|
8
|
8
|
Are the patterns confounded?
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Observations
|
1299
|
1299
|
1175
|
1175
|
1175
|
1175
|
1099
|
1099
|
1091
|
1091
|
1024
|
1024
|
Notes: BASE group is richer country regions that are democratic. All models use a robust estimator. See the notes for table A8. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gdp
|
I
|
II
|
III
|
IV
|
V
|
VI
|
VII
|
VIII
|
IX
|
X
|
1#0. Low income, not democratic
|
|
-0.664
|
-1.190***
|
-2.095***
|
-2.081***
|
-1.961***
|
-1.885***
|
-1.810***
|
-2.120***
|
-2.366***
|
|
(0.408)
|
(0.224)
|
(0.185)
|
(0.188)
|
(0.261)
|
(0.260)
|
(0.243)
|
(0.301)
|
(0.350)
|
1#1. Low income, democratic
|
|
-0.367
|
-1.244***
|
-1.622***
|
-1.608***
|
-1.846***
|
-1.877***
|
-1.851***
|
-2.070***
|
-2.220***
|
|
(0.434)
|
(0.228)
|
(0.184)
|
(0.202)
|
(0.195)
|
(0.257)
|
(0.252)
|
(0.324)
|
(0.312)
|
2#0. Lower middle income, not democratic
|
|
-0.784***
|
-1.426***
|
-2.093***
|
-2.050***
|
-1.845***
|
-1.578***
|
-1.210***
|
-1.128***
|
-1.259***
|
|
(0.275)
|
(0.178)
|
(0.168)
|
(0.155)
|
(0.206)
|
(0.259)
|
(0.237)
|
(0.274)
|
(0.267)
|
2#1. Lower middle income, democratic
|
|
-0.156
|
-1.150***
|
-1.644***
|
-1.628***
|
-1.491***
|
-1.126***
|
-0.530**
|
-0.144
|
-0.193
|
|
(0.227)
|
(0.161)
|
(0.143)
|
(0.133)
|
(0.211)
|
(0.287)
|
(0.267)
|
(0.289)
|
(0.264)
|
3#0. Upper middle income, not democratic
|
|
-1.256***
|
-1.329***
|
-1.927***
|
-1.857***
|
-1.744***
|
-1.669***
|
-1.604***
|
-1.729***
|
-1.803***
|
|
(0.224)
|
(0.171)
|
(0.125)
|
(0.157)
|
(0.125)
|
(0.177)
|
(0.152)
|
(0.202)
|
(0.224)
|
3#1. Upper middle income, democratic
|
|
-0.910***
|
-0.983***
|
-1.192***
|
-1.182***
|
-1.205***
|
-1.131***
|
-1.017***
|
-1.175***
|
-1.344***
|
|
(0.185)
|
(0.128)
|
(0.110)
|
(0.105)
|
(0.105)
|
(0.156)
|
(0.127)
|
(0.141)
|
(0.178)
|
4#0. High income (non-OECD), not democratic
|
|
n/a
|
-1.619***
|
-2.149***
|
-1.974***
|
-2.025***
|
-1.933***
|
-2.164***
|
-1.911***
|
-1.959***
|
|
n/a
|
(0.205)
|
(0.258)
|
(0.323)
|
(0.135)
|
(0.195)
|
(0.222)
|
(0.424)
|
(0.377)
|
4#1. High income (non-OECD), democratic
|
|
-0.565***
|
-0.645***
|
-0.801***
|
-0.748***
|
-0.667***
|
-0.654***
|
-0.531***
|
-0.578***
|
-0.654***
|
|
(0.156)
|
(0.107)
|
(0.100)
|
(0.090)
|
(0.121)
|
(0.130)
|
(0.115)
|
(0.150)
|
(0.149)
|
5#0. High income (OECD), not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
5#1. High income (OECD), democratic BASE
|
|
3.203***
|
1.755***
|
3.722***
|
3.603***
|
3.047***
|
3.107***
|
3.000***
|
2.708***
|
2.452***
|
|
(0.450)
|
(0.417)
|
(0.224)
|
(0.223)
|
(0.277)
|
(0.334)
|
(0.301)
|
(0.381)
|
(0.391)
|
Constant
|
2.963***
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.287)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
gdppc
|
0.000009***
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.000003)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
poldemoc
|
0.713***
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.076)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
gini
|
|
-0.005
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.008)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
hci (lagged
one period)
|
|
|
0.499***
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.091)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.158
|
0.280
|
0.213
|
0.151
|
0.144
|
0.120
|
0.107
|
0.095
|
0.084
|
0.089
|
F-value
|
85.07***
|
26.72***
|
45.06***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
Countries
|
167
|
124
|
137
|
169
|
169
|
169
|
169
|
169
|
169
|
169
|
Years
|
26
|
25
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
Year fixed effects
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Observations
|
2278
|
769
|
2010
|
2288
|
2288
|
2288
|
2288
|
2288
|
2288
|
2288
|
Notes: BASE group is high-income (OECD) and democratic countries. Models I, II, and III use a robust estimator. Models IV, V, VI, VII, VIII, IX, and X use a quantile estimator at the 20th, 25th, 40th, 50th, 60th, 75th, and 80th percentiles, respectively. The constant for Model I includes all countries, regardless of income group, ceteris paribus. All models use three controls: youth population (pop024); urban population (urban) and trade (trade). The estimates for the various controls are excluded to save space. A pseudo R-squared is reported for the quantile regression. Not applicable (n/a) means there are no applicable countries for these groups. The various standard errors are given in parentheses. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Dependent variable: pse/gov
|
I
|
II
|
III
|
IV
|
V
|
VI
|
VII
|
VIII
|
IX
|
X
|
1#0. Low income, not democratic
|
|
0.967
|
1.180*
|
-0.341
|
-0.274
|
0.052
|
-0.162
|
-1.109*
|
-0.854
|
-0.754
|
|
(1.063)
|
(0.656)
|
(0.787)
|
(0.700)
|
(0.972)
|
(0.696)
|
(0.673)
|
(0.991)
|
(1.007)
|
1#1. Low income, democratic
|
|
1.933*
|
0.999
|
3.255***
|
2.717***
|
2.435***
|
1.290**
|
-0.190
|
-0.770
|
-0.523
|
|
(1.137)
|
(0.666)
|
(0.765)
|
(0.539)
|
(0.745)
|
(0.581)
|
(0.475)
|
(1.060)
|
(1.045)
|
2#0. Lower middle income, not democratic
|
|
0.891
|
-0.048
|
0.215
|
0.286
|
0.918
|
0.614
|
0.335
|
0.879
|
0.581
|
|
(0.729)
|
(0.519)
|
(0.531)
|
(0.568)
|
(0.676)
|
(0.531)
|
(0.492)
|
(0.771)
|
(0.753)
|
2#1. Lower middle income, democratic
|
|
1.694***
|
1.710***
|
2.115***
|
1.905***
|
1.878***
|
1.661***
|
1.506***
|
1.885**
|
1.730**
|
|
(0.588)
|
(0.465)
|
(0.286)
|
(0.120)
|
(0.547)
|
(0.419)
|
(0.253)
|
(0.743)
|
(0.814)
|
3#0. Upper middle income, not democratic
|
|
0.323
|
1.569***
|
-2.129**
|
-1.405*
|
0.003
|
-0.131
|
-0.353
|
1.465**
|
1.055
|
|
(0.584)
|
(0.506)
|
(0.860)
|
(0.802)
|
(0.638)
|
(0.371)
|
(0.509)
|
(0.717)
|
(0.755)
|
3#1. Upper middle income, democratic
|
|
0.237
|
1.188***
|
0.811***
|
0.831***
|
1.344***
|
1.205***
|
0.967***
|
1.514***
|
1.371**
|
|
(0.478)
|
(0.370)
|
(0.236)
|
(0.263)
|
(0.371)
|
(0.179)
|
(0.254)
|
(0.553)
|
(0.592)
|
4#0. High income (non-OECD), not democratic
|
|
n/a
|
-1.415**
|
-2.972***
|
-3.211***
|
-3.372***
|
-3.107***
|
-3.757***
|
-1.624
|
-1.034
|
|
n/a
|
(0.581)
|
(0.304)
|
(0.387)
|
(0.627)
|
(0.356)
|
(0.303)
|
(1.293)
|
(1.085)
|
4#1. High income (non-OECD), democratic
|
|
-0.117
|
-0.112
|
-0.914***
|
-0.685**
|
0.065
|
0.308
|
0.413
|
0.821**
|
0.326
|
|
(0.400)
|
(0.320)
|
(0.218)
|
(0.327)
|
(0.425)
|
(0.342)
|
(0.278)
|
(0.401)
|
(0.425)
|
5#0. High income (OECD), not democratic
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
5#1. High income (OECD), democratic BASE
|
|
1.036
|
0.998
|
4.287***
|
3.603***
|
2.246**
|
0.885
|
-0.810
|
1.296
|
3.350***
|
|
(1.164)
|
(1.225)
|
(0.481)
|
(0.664)
|
(0.907)
|
(0.643)
|
(0.726)
|
(1.110)
|
(1.064)
|
Constant
|
1.989**
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.841)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
gdppc
|
-0.000015**
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.000007)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
poldemoc
|
1.368***
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.229)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
gini
|
|
0.098***
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.021)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
hci (lagged
one period)
|
|
|
0.404
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(0.271)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
R-squared
|
0.205
|
0.295
|
0.279
|
0.081
|
0.093
|
0.121
|
0.146
|
0.166
|
0.189
|
0.193
|
F-value
|
105.86***
|
26.91***
|
58.31***
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
n/a
|
Countries
|
164
|
124
|
134
|
165
|
165
|
165
|
165
|
165
|
165
|
165
|
Years
|
26
|
24
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
26
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Year fixed effects
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Observations
|
2060
|
718
|
1820
|
2069
|
2069
|
2069
|
2069
|
2069
|
2069
|
2069
|
Notes: BASE group is high-income (OECD) and democratic countries. Models I, II, and III use a robust estimator. Models IV, V, VI, VII, VIII, IX, and X use a quantile estimator at the 20th, 25th, 40th, 50th, 60th, 75th, and 80th percentiles, respectively. See the notes for table A12. Significance levels: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
|
|
Abstract We examine the association between economic development and two measures of public spending on education: the “national effort” (public spending on education as a proportion of GDP) and “budget share” (public spending on education as a proportion of total government spending). Using panel data for a large sample of countries from 1989 to 2015, we compare mean levels of national effort and budget share measures for economically and politically distinct groups of countries. We find that economically more developed (richer) countries are characterised by a higher national effort and a lower budget share than less economically developed countries. This implies that richer countries, on average, have larger public sectors than poorer countries, consistent with Wagner’s law and Baumol’s “cost disease” hypothesis.
Keywords: education spending; Wagner’s law; Baumol’s cost disease; economic development; democracy
JEL: H52, I22, I25
1 Introduction
Public spending accounts for the lion’s share of the financing of education in most countries; indeed, the “massification” of education is made possible through public provision. Two headline measures of public education spending, namely the “national effort” (total public spending on education as a proportion of GDP) and the “budget share” (total public spending on education as a proportion of total government spending), are commonly used to compare the financing of public education across countries. Whether or not richer (developed) countries spend more on public education than do poorer (developing) countries, regardless of which of the two ratio measures is used, is a matter for empirical inquiry. In this paper, we therefore aim to test whether, on average, richer (developed) economies have larger public education sectors than poorer (developing) economies, in both national effort and budget share terms. As well as providing a global comparative view of education spending patterns, this offers a novel perspective on the implications for the size of the public sector (total government spending as a percentage of GDP) as income per capita increases.
The idea that the size of the public sector is positively related to the level of economic development is not new. Wagner’s “law of increasing state activity”, for instance, points to an apparent empirical regularity whereby an increasing share of overall government expenditure in the national economy is associated with rising income per capita. Wagner ( 1892; 1958) attributed expansion of the public sector to continued cultural and economic progress, which has associated social, welfare, regulatory and infrastructural requirements that necessitate a growing role for government spending in the economy (Kuckuck, 2014).
Baumol’s “cost disease” hypothesis (Baumol, 1967; Baumol and Bowen, 1966) also predicts a growing public sector as a proportion of the economy. This is attributed to higher labour intensity and lower productivity growth in the public sector (for example, in education and medical care) than in the private sector. Technological advancement, innovation and substitution of capital for labour lead to increases in wages in the private sector, which are mirrored as cost increases in the public sector. Under this explanation, public sector expansion is largely cost-driven.
The aim of this paper is to examine whether there exist differences in the mean levels of the national effort or budget share measures of education spending for economically (and politically) distinct groups of countries. By exploring the patterns of public education spending, we provide, as a by-product, insights into differences in the size of government for richer versus poorer countries. If the national effort and budget share measures are both larger for richer than for poorer countries, differences in the size of government are indeterminate in the absence of additional information. However, if richer countries have a larger national effort, but a smaller budget share than poorer countries, then this necessarily implies that richer countries, on average, have larger public sectors than poorer countries.
Several hypotheses can be formulated from the relevant empirical literature. The ability of publicly provided education to reach all parts of society (the massification of education), makes education a useful conduit through which social, cultural and economic progress (for example, human capital development) can be advanced. Public financing of education is, therefore, expected to expand along with overall public spending as part of governments’ efforts to promote economic growth and development, especially if education is viewed as a merit good and a productive component of public spending.
To measure economic development, income per capita has been widely used as an explanatory variable in studies of education spending (Shin, 2020; Afonso and Alves, 2017; Cockx and Francken, 2016; Garritzmann and Seng, 2016; Dragomirescu-Gaina, 2015). The intuition is that richer, more developed, countries have greater resources with which to fund various social programmes, such as education (Brown and Hunter, 2004). The evidence suggests a positive relationship between the national effort measure and economic development (Shin, 2020; Cockx and Francken, 2016; Akanbi and Schoeman, 2010; Huber, Mustillo and Stephens, 2008; Busemeyer, 2007; Stasavage, 2005; Baqir, 2002; Ram, 1995; Tilak, 1989).
Evidence concerning the budget share is more limited. The few studies employing this measure mostly report a positive association between budget share and economic development (Fosu, 2010; Stasavage, 2005; Baqir, 2002), although the relationship is not always significant, and the studies by Fosu and Stasavage are concerned only with African countries. Angelov ( 2019) provides an example of a more recent study that employs a budget share measure of education spending to compare European Union countries’ education spending but does not investigate the relationship between education spending and economic development. However, it is reasonable to suppose that, as countries grow and develop, the size and complexity of their respective public sectors (the variety of public goods to be financed by government) will grow, so education could end up constituting a reducing share of the total budget allocation, ceteris paribus. A negative association between the budget share and the level of development would be likely if education is a “necessity” with respect to total government spending.
The type of political regime is also relevant in an analysis of education spending. Regardless of the outcome measure (national effort or budget share), democratic countries are expected to spend more on education, ceteris paribus. It is well documented in the political economy literature that democracy is positively associated with the public provision of basic services, such as education (Baum and Lake, 2003; Lake and Baum, 2001), although there are different views about the exact mechanisms underpinning this association (Harding and Stasavage, 2014). On the one hand, spending more on socially productive public goods, such as education, provides a politically popular way for governments to demonstrate accountability and broaden their voter pool. Brown and Hunter ( 2004), for example, make this point with respect to spending on primary education in Latin America. On the other hand, evidence also exists for democratic developing countries (e.g., Brazil) that poorer electorates prefer government to allocate spending to areas other than education (Bursztyn, 2016); hence, a negative association between democracy and education spending is possible. However, overall, many empirical studies find evidence that public education spending is higher in democracies (Murshed et al., 2022; Shin, 2020; Garritzmann and Seng, 2016; Avelino, Brown and Hunter, 2015; Stasavage, 2005; Baqir, 2002). Consequently, in our analysis of public education spending, we categorise countries by political regime (democratic versus nondemocratic) as well as by levels of income, while controlling for other social and economic factors.
The rest of this paper proceeds as follows. In section 2, we describe the data and outline the empirical method to be applied. In section 3, we report the empirical results, including checks for robustness. The main findings are discussed in section 4, and section 5 concludes.
2 Data and empirical methods
We use annual panel data from 1989 to 2015 for up to 193 countries, although the number of available observations depends on the variables being considered. Table 1 presents details of the data collected. Two different continuous outcome measures for public education spending are examined, namely the national effort (total public spending on education as a proportion of GDP, pse/gdp) and budget share (total public spending on education as a proportion of total government spending, pse/gov). Three key categorical explanatory measures are used because our aim is to compare education spending for economically and politically distinct groupings of countries. The level of economic development (ypc2015) is represented by a set of dummy variables, categorising countries into five groups adapted from the World Bank’s Country and Lending Groups as at 2015. These are based on gross national income (GNI) per capita in US dollars using the World Bank’s Atlas method, which smooths exchange rate fluctuations and provides a comparable crosscountry measure for grouping countries by income per capita. The sample contains representation across the full range of income levels. The richest group consists of the 21 wealthiest, long-standing Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) “core” countries; these constitute the same set of countries examined by Busemeyer ( 2007). The other four groups are high-income (mostly non-OECD), upper-middle-income, lower-middle-income, and low-income countries. Appendix table A1 gives a list of countries included in each group.
Table 1Data definitions and sources DISPLAY Table
An alternative classification of countries by development status is based on a binary richer-country/poorer-country split, defined in terms of regional country groupings (region). Appendix table A2 provides a list of countries included in each group. A binary perspective on education spending patterns can be explored by using a pair of regional dummy variables representing rich versus poor countries.
A classification of countries depending on whether they are democratic or nondemocratic (poldemoc) is used to represent different political regime types. A classification of countries by regime type (democratic versus non-democratic) is not listed because this can vary over time. For each of the key categorical explanatory measures, sample selection bias is mitigated because the economic groupings of countries are invariant over the study period, and the political regime type (democratic versus non-democratic) typically varies only very slowly over time in most countries.
Several potentially important control variables are included in the analyses. The size of the school-going population up to age 24 ( pop024) captures the positive demographic effect of the proportion of young people on education spending (Busemeyer, 2007, 2008; Brown and Hunter, 2004; Castles, 1989). The urbanisation ratio ( urban) captures the positive effect of a greater concentration of the total population in urban areas on a government’s propensity to act in favour of fundamental social needs, such as education (Akanbi and Schoeman, 2010; Huber, Mustillo and Stephens, 2008; Avelino, Brown and Hunter, 2005; Baqir, 2002; Schultz, 1988). Total international trade ( trade) is often included in empirical analyses of education spending (Ozkok, 2017; Busemeyer, 2009; Huber, Mustillo and Stephens, 2008; Iversen and Stephens, 2008; Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo, 2001). This allows for two possible effects: a positive compensation effect, in which government “compensates” society for the adverse effects of globalisation through greater social and welfare spending, and a negative efficiency effect, in which government sees increased globalisation as a mechanism to promote competitiveness, reducing the need for social and welfare spending. 1 Which trade effect dominates is an empirical question.
A number of other control variables are used for robustness checking. The size of the population aged 65 and above ( pop65) represents a demographic cohort that competes for education spending in the form of transfer payments to the elderly population (Shin, 2020; Busemeyer, 2008; Iversen and Stephens, 2008; Avelino, Brown and Hunter, 2005; Brown and Hunter, 1999). Military spending ( military) is also expected to compete for education’s share of public resources, especially in countries with a large military presence (Shin, 2020; Baqir, 2002). The fiscal balance ( fiscbal) and gross public debt stock ( debt) are both expected to have implications for how much of the public purse is allocated to education (Busemeyer, 2009; Huber, Mustillo and Stephens, 2008; Tilak, 1989, 1990). Human capital development, as measured by the Penn World Table (Feenstra, Inklaar and Timmer, 2015) human capital index ( hci), is not typically used in this empirical literature, but is included to control for the current-period stock of human capital as a proxy for the quality of education in a country.
Pooled descriptive statistics for each variable are reported in appendix table A3. Data availability is a pervasive problem in the literature on education spending. The two measures of education spending are available for fewer countries (N) and a smaller average number of time-series observations than are any of the explanatory variables: the sample is roughly half as large in most cases.
The approach we adopt – one-way or two-way ANOVA and ANCOVA, with the focus being a two-way factorial analysis of covariance – aims for a descriptive characterisation of average differences between broad groupings of countries, rather than implying specific causal linkages. The method is a variant of fixed effects estimation, but instead of estimating country fixed effects, more highly aggregated group effects are estimated. An advantage of this method is that it is possible to estimate mean differences in the groups of interest while controlling for other relevant variables. The regression equations include interactions of political and economic dummy variables, allowing for different intercepts in each political-economic group. However, no other interaction terms are included, and the parameters for the controls are assumed to be constant across all countries. Allowing for heterogeneous group parameters would mean having to interact all the group dummies with the control variables, leading to a proliferation of explanatory variables and excessive multicollinearity
The models in equations (1) and (2) represent the empirical specifications to be tested. Separate single-equation models are estimated for national effort and budget share. In the model in equation (1), we include interaction terms between categorical variables for five economic groups and two political groups (democratic, non-democratic), yielding 10 categories. In the model in equation (2), we include interaction terms between categorical variables for two regional groups (richer, poorer) and the two political groups, yielding four categories.
 | (1) |
 | (2) |
Here, Y is either the national effort or budget share measure of total education spending; Ej ( j = 1, …, 5) constitutes a set of five (1/0) dummy variables, one for each of the five GNI per capita country groups; Pm ( m = 0, 1) is a set of two (1/0) dummy variables, one for each of the political groupings, i.e., democratic, ( m = 1) or non-democratic ( m = 0); Rr ( r = 0, 1) is a set of two (1/0) dummy variables, one for each of the two regional country groups (poorer or richer); Xn ( n = 1, …, N) is a set of continuous control variables comprising a minimum of three or a maximum of eight controls; and ε is a generic random error term. Subscripts i and t denote observations for country i and time t, respectively, and ajm, arm and βn are parameters.
In order to focus on differences in national effort and budget share across groups, we reparameterise equations (1) and (2). We include an intercept term and, if there are k distinct economic/political categories, k-1 dummies are included, to avoid perfect multicollinearity. The base category is then represented by the intercept. For equation (1), the base category is the group of 21 OECD countries that are democratic. For equation (2), the base category is richer countries (or, more accurately, regions comprising the richest countries of the world) that are democratic. In the reparameterised model, the coefficients on the interactions between the dummy variables represent mean differences in the education spending measure for the relevant composite economic/political category relative to the base category. So, for example, for comparisons of different economic groups with a common political categorisation, a series of positive (negative) mean differences indicates that poorer countries have, on average, higher (lower) levels of the education spending measure relative to the relevant base category.
The least-squares dummy-variable (LSDV) estimator with heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors is used to obtain the baseline set of results. We undertake several types of robustness check. First, we report quantile (median) regression and robust regression estimates of the parameters to check for sensitivity to outlier observations. 2 Second, we examine a number of different estimators of the standard errors for the LSDV results. 3 These include one-way (country or year) and two-way (country and year) clustering, Newey-West heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent (HAC) standard errors (Newey and West, 1987, 1994), and Driscoll and Kraay’s ( 1998) standard errors, which are robust to heteroskedastic, autocorrelated and cross-sectionally dependent errors. Third, we examine the effects of including time dummies to control for year effects and adding additional control variables ( hci, pop65, military, fiscbal, debt). Fourth, we examine the effects of using a continuous measure of GDP per capita ( gdppc) as a way to check whether the substantive pattern of results is noticeably different from using our preferred GNI per capita categorisation of countries. Finally, we explore the implications of including a Gini index of income inequality ( gini) and hci lagged by one period, and examining different quantiles (0.2, 0.25, 0.4, 0.5, 0.6, 0.75, 0.8) for the quantile estimator; with all these additional specifications we incorporate the main controls ( pop024, urban, and trade). 4
3 Results
Table 2 reports the main empirical estimates for the national effort and budget share, for the model with 10 economic/political categories; the corresponding results for the model with four categories are reported in table 3. In the tables of results, the coefficient estimates are labelled “j#m” (j = 1, …, 5; m = 0, 1) for equation (1) and “r#m” (r = 0, 1; m = 0, 1) for equation (2). “BASE” represents the intercept estimate. Each estimation method (LSDV, quantile, and robust) is applied to a model with no controls (A), and with three controls (B). Note that there are no non-democratic OECD or richer countries, so there are no results for these combinations.
The most important finding from table 2 (equation (1)), and table 3 (equation (2)) is a reversal in the pattern of mean differences for the levels of the national effort compared to the budget share. Interaction of the economic and political dummies (table 2), or regional and political dummies (table 3), reveals a pattern of significant negative mean differences (compared to the base category) for the national effort but positive mean differences for the budget share. These patterns are similar regardless of whether no controls or three controls are used. When we control for political categorisation, richer (poorer) countries tend to spend more, on average, in national effort (budget share) terms, although the association is not always monotonic.
Whether a country has a democratic political system is associated with its education spending patterns, with significant mean differences within the same economic or regional group. For example, regardless of the spending measure (national effort or budget share), when we control for economic or regional group, democratic countries tend to spend more on average than their non-democratic counterparts. Table 4 reports a summary of the results from a series of pairwise Wald tests, conducted on the robust regression estimates obtained from tables 2 and 3, for the null hypothesis of parameter equality (i.e., no difference in the mean levels of education spending for countries with democratic versus non-democratic systems, within the same economic or regional group). For example, we can test whether the mean level of education spending in low-income democratic countries differs significantly from that of low-income countries that are not democratic. Because the intercept term is the common base category for all economic/political groups, we can ignore that and focus on the differences in the relevant coefficient estimates. We are conducting multiple hypothesis tests, which inflates the overall “familywise” Type I error rate, so we apply a Bonferroni correction to the level of significance used for each individual test by dividing the familywise error rate (set at 0.05) by the number of tests (for example, 0.05/4 tests = 0.0125). Even with such a correction, most pairwise comparisons still reveal statistically significant differences.
Table 2Mean differences in the national effort and budget share by income group and regime type DISPLAY Table
Table 3Mean differences in the national effort and budget share by country region and regime type DISPLAY Table
Table 4Wald tests for parameter equality of the factor-variable interactions DISPLAY Table
Estimated coefficients on the control variables have the expected signs. Both the youth population and urbanisation variables have positive coefficients. The coefficient on the trade variable is positive in most cases, which supports the compensation hypothesis.
The empirical patterns are generally robust to the use of two alternative estimation methods (quantile and robust, reported in tables 2 and 3) and to the use of alternative standard errors for the LSDV estimation (reported in appendix tables A4-A7). The largest standard errors are those clustered by country (as opposed to by year or by country and year). This is not surprising, because there are many countries for which very few observations are available for the dependent variable, and this makes it more difficult to estimate coefficients precisely when clustering by country.
Robustness checks considering differences in model specification (including year dummies and employing more than three controls) are reported in appendix tables A8 and A9 (using LSDV estimation), and tables A10 and A11 (using robust estimation); for these, only the more parsimonious regional and political specification (in equation (2)) is used, because a richer versus poorer interpretation is the key focus of our study. We make three observations about these additional robustness results. Firstly, including year dummies leaves the substantive patterns of mean differences unchanged; signs of the estimated coefficients are unaffected in all cases, although there are some changes in marginal levels of statistical significance for some of the budget share results. Secondly, if a robust estimator is used to deal with outliers, the empirical patterns are exhibited more clearly regardless of the specification used. Thirdly, the signs of the coefficients on the various additional controls ( hci, pop65, military, fiscbal and debt) are as expected in most cases. Introducing an additional control each time entails an increasingly more complex specification that either does not confound or only partially confounds the empirical patterns. 5 The most comprehensive specification (using eight controls) provides additional support for the empirical patterns in the baseline results. Overall, the observed empirical patterns of negative (positive) mean differences for the national effort (budget share), compared to the base category, are robust to the use of different estimators for the coefficients and standard errors, and to plausible changes to the specification.
Several additional robustness checks use the robust estimator (or, where applicable, the quantile estimator), including the main controls ( pop024, urban, and trade) in all cases. These results are reported in appendix tables A12 and A13. Firstly, to check that the general patterns for both measures of education spending are maintained when using a continuous measure of income per capita, the robust estimator is used with GDP per capita ( gdppc) and political democracy ( poldemoc) as explanatory variables. This also checks whether using GDP per capita (instead of our preferred World Bank Atlas method of GNI per capita country groupings) reveals anything noticeably different about the data patterns. The results are reported in column I of tables A12 and A13. These specifications are consistent with the empirical patterns observed in the main results, with a significant positive coefficient on GDP per capita for national effort and a significant negative coefficient for budget share. 6
Secondly, the effect of including a measure of income inequality (gini) (column II of tables A12 and A13) is explored because within-country disparities in income are likely to influence education attainments and, hence, the political motives behind the funding of education. However, poor data coverage plagues the use of a Gini measure (or any other measure) of income inequality, limiting the extent to which meaningful inferences can be made. Nonetheless, the general patterns are maintained, albeit with some inconclusive effects; the latter is not surprising given the considerably reduced number of observations available when introducing a Gini measure. The Gini coefficient itself is not statistically significant in the national effort regression but has a statistically significant positive sign for the budget share measure.
Thirdly, we control for the effect on current education spending of the lagged level of education by including the human capital index (hci) variable lagged one period. Results are reported in column III in tables A12 and A13. For the most part, the general patterns noted previously are maintained.
Fourthly, in addition to the benchmark median or 0.5 quantile regression (estimates at the 50th percentile for the sample), estimates are also produced for other quantiles (20th, 25th, 40th, 60th, 75th, and 80th percentiles). Results are reported in columns IV to X in tables A12 and A13. Overall, the general patterns of predominantly positive (negative) association between the level of economic development and national effort (budget share) in education spending are maintained.
4 Discussion
From the perspective of the 2 × 2 categorisation in equation (2), richer (developed) countries tend to make a greater national effort with respect to education (they spend more on average on education as a share of GDP). In contrast, they tend to have lower budget shares (they spend less on average on education as a share of total government spending) relative to poorer (less-developed) countries.
In terms of national effort, richer country governments do not necessarily value education more highly than poorer country governments, but they have greater capacity to generate income from taxes. They can raise more income from taxes because they have larger formal private-sector economies. They are therefore less fiscally constrained and can spend more on areas such as education. The inability of poorer-country governments to extract revenue from a relatively small tax base constrains not only the growth of these countries’ public sectors – a point noted by Holcombe ( 2005), albeit in more general terms – but also their national effort with respect to education. Poorer countries tend to have greater informal-sector, cashbased economic activity relative to the size of the formal private-sector economy (Schneider and Enste, 2000), which makes it more difficult for governments in such countries to extract the tax revenue necessary to finance public education.
From a budget share perspective, poorer countries tend to spend more on education as a share of total government spending because they generally have smaller public sectors, which means education tends to comprise a larger share of the total public sector budget. However, richer countries are more likely to have large, complex public sectors with a greater variety of fiscal components to be financed from tax revenue. For example, a larger role of the state in providing various kinds of welfare support in richer countries could lead to other forms of public spending, such as education, being assigned a lower priority. An implication of this reasoning is that publicly provided education, as a whole, might take on the characteristics of a necessity with respect to public-sector spending in richer countries. Consequently, from a fiscal varieties perspective, education’s share of the total “fiscal pie” tends to be smaller in richer countries with larger public sectors and a greater variety of fiscal components to be paid for from the public purse, explaining why the budget share allocation to education spending is lower (higher) in richer (poorer) countries. There is also a political dimension to this explanation. The priorities for education spending differ among poorer countries with contrasting levels (or states) of democracy. Political pressures compel governments in poorer, democratic countries to spend more on areas such as education, and when poorer democratic countries grow, they can more easily generate income from taxes to satisfy political pressures to spend more on education.
For comparable levels of economic development, democratic governments tend to spend more on education. On the other hand, our empirical results for the robust estimator with controls (table 3 and table A11) show that poorer, non-democratic countries have low budget shares that are not necessarily much different from those of richer (democratic) countries. This suggests that the former not only have smaller public sectors, but also have lower allocations to education from the public purse. This might partly explain why such countries remain poor and less developed.
The observation that richer (developed) countries, on average, tend to spend more on education as a share of GDP and less on education as a share of total government spending than poorer (less-developed) countries, implies that richer countries on average have larger public sectors (total government spending as a share of GDP) than poorer countries. This follows from the identity (E/Y)/(E/G) ≡ G/Y, where E is public education spending; Y is GDP and G is total government spending. If the national effort, E/Y, and budget share, E/G, are both larger for richer than for poorer countries, then differences in the size of government, G/Y, between richer and poorer countries will depend on the relative size of the increases. However, if, as our results suggest, richer countries have a larger national effort, but smaller budget share than poorer countries, then the identity necessarily implies that richer countries have larger public sectors than poorer countries.
Table 5Three inequality propositions DISPLAY Table
Table 5 summarises the key empirical findings in this study in the form of three inequality propositions representing the characteristics of richer compared to poorer countries. To the best of our knowledge, such a characterisation of education spending (Propositions 1 and 2) and, by implication, the size of the public sector (Proposition 3) has not been presented in this form before. Because the inequalities in Propositions 1 and 2, based on our empirical results, are different for national effort compared to budget share, they imply that richer (poorer) countries have larger (smaller) public sectors. 7 Proposition 3 logically follows as a consequence of Propositions 1 and 2; however, if empirical analysis of education spending had revealed the same direction of association for both measures, then Proposition 3 would not necessarily result. The same could be said for any other national effort or budget share measure of fiscal expenditure. Therefore, our analysis provides a novel way to characterise differences in the size of government at different levels of income.
5 Conclusion
We examine whether there are mean differences in the levels of public spending on education for two widely used national-level measures (national effort and budget share) for different economic (or regional) and political groupings of countries. Controlling for the state of democracy, we find that richer (poorer) countries tend to spend, on average, a larger (smaller) share of GDP on education, but a smaller (larger) share of total government spending on education. Richer countries, on average, make a greater national educational effort, whereas poorer countries allocate a greater budget share to education. By implication, richer countries, on average, have larger public sectors than poorer countries. In addition, for comparable levels of income, democratic countries tend to spend more on education than is the case for their non-democratic counterparts.
The findings with respect to levels of income can be summarised in the form of three inequality propositions. Examination of education spending patterns with respect to the national effort and budget share measures provides indirect support for a positive association between the size of government and income, consistent with Wagner’s law and Baumol’s “cost disease” hypothesis. Peacock and Scott ( 2000) note that different components of government expenditure might grow at different rates. Therefore, from the perspective of public policy analysis, future research might focus on testing the inequality propositions identified in this study with respect to other components of the government’s budget allocation (for example, the national effort and budget share of health, military, or welfare spending).
Appendix
Table A1List of countries and territories by GNI per capita group in 2015 (ypc2015) DISPLAY Table Table A2List of countries by two regional country groups (region) DISPLAY Table Table A3Descriptive statistics DISPLAY Table Table A4Mean differences in the national effort by income group and regime type – alternative standard error estimates DISPLAY Table Table A5Mean differences in the budget share by income group and regime type – alternative standard error estimates DISPLAY Table Table A6Mean differences in the national effort by country region and regime type – alternative standard error estimates DISPLAY Table Table A7Mean differences in the budget share by country region and regime type – alternative standard error estimates DISPLAY Table Table A8A summary of changes to the model specification (national effort and LSDV estimator) DISPLAY Table Table A9A summary of changes to the model specification (budget share and LSDV estimator) DISPLAY Table Table A10A summary of changes to the model specification (national effort and robust estimator) DISPLAY Table Table A11A summary of changes to the model specification (budget share and robust estimator) DISPLAY Table Table A12A summary of additional robustness checks (national effort with robust and quantile estimators) DISPLAY Table Table A13A summary of additional robustness checks (budget share with robust and quantile estimators) DISPLAY Table
Funding
Mark Millin wishes to acknowledge financial support in the form of doctoral scholarship funding from the National Research Foundation (NRF) of South Africa and the University of Otago, and a publication bursary from the University of Otago.
Notes
* We thank two anonymous reviewers, and participants at the 59th Annual Conference of the New Zealand Association of Economists and at the University of Otago, Department of Economics, Brown Bag seminar for helpful comments and suggestions.
1 More detailed explanations of the compensation and efficiency hypotheses are provided by Walter ( 2010), Adserà and Boix ( 2002), Garrett ( 1998a, 1998b, 2001), Rodrik ( 1998), Katzenstein ( 1985), Ruggie ( 1982) and Cameron ( 1978).
2 Robust estimation uses the “rreg” routine in Stata. An initial screening based on Cook’s distance is used to remove gross outliers. Starting values are then calculated, and Huber iterations performed, followed by biweight iterations, to determine the down-weighting of any outliers; see Hamilton ( 1991) for further details.
3 Baum, Nichols and Schaffer ( 2010) and Cameron and Miller ( 2015) provide a practical discussion of clusterrobust inference. All estimates are obtained using Stata; one-way clustering of standard errors is performed using “cluster(country)” or “cluster(year)”. Two-way clustering is performed with the user-written program “vce2way” (Yoo, 2017).
4 We are grateful to a reviewer for suggesting these additional robustness checks.
5 Partial confounding refers to the case where only poorer countries that are not democratic are shown to have significantly different means from the base group (richer and democratic countries), and with the expected sign. No confounding refers to the case where either poorer country groups (irrespective of the state of democracy) or poorer and democratic countries are shown to have significantly different means from the base group, and with the expected sign.
6 Alternative specifications were also fitted using GDP per capita and its squared and cubed values, along with the political democracy variable and main controls. In all cases considered, the main results are supported, i.e., the coefficient on the linear GDP per capita term maintains the same sign, is not too dissimilar in size, and remains statistically significant. Note that, in the main results, non-linearities are allowed for by estimating piecewise linear effects, i.e., average effects for different income groupings of countries.
7 We note two points relating to these inequalities. First, it does not matter whether E, Y and G are measured in real or nominal terms, provided both the numerator and denominator of the relevant ratio are measured in the same nominal or real terms (using the same deflator). Second, the same estimated size of the public sector in any one country, as given by sources such as the IMF, cannot simply be obtained by taking the quotient of the national effort and budget share for that country because these education spending measures are estimates. The quotient will give only a rough approximation of the size of government, especially for countries that have less accurate education spending data.
* We thank two anonymous reviewers, and participants at the 59th Annual Conference of the New Zealand Association of Economists and at the University of Otago, Department of Economics, Brown Bag seminar for helpful comments and suggestions.
1 More detailed explanations of the compensation and efficiency hypotheses are provided by Walter ( 2010), Adserà and Boix ( 2002), Garrett ( 1998a, 1998b, 2001), Rodrik ( 1998), Katzenstein ( 1985), Ruggie ( 1982) and Cameron ( 1978).
2 Robust estimation uses the “rreg” routine in Stata. An initial screening based on Cook’s distance is used to remove gross outliers. Starting values are then calculated, and Huber iterations performed, followed by biweight iterations, to determine the down-weighting of any outliers; see Hamilton ( 1991) for further details.
3 Baum, Nichols and Schaffer ( 2010) and Cameron and Miller ( 2015) provide a practical discussion of clusterrobust inference. All estimates are obtained using Stata; one-way clustering of standard errors is performed using “cluster(country)” or “cluster(year)”. Two-way clustering is performed with the user-written program “vce2way” (Yoo, 2017).
4 We are grateful to a reviewer for suggesting these additional robustness checks.
5 Partial confounding refers to the case where only poorer countries that are not democratic are shown to have significantly different means from the base group (richer and democratic countries), and with the expected sign. No confounding refers to the case where either poorer country groups (irrespective of the state of democracy) or poorer and democratic countries are shown to have significantly different means from the base group, and with the expected sign.
6 Alternative specifications were also fitted using GDP per capita and its squared and cubed values, along with the political democracy variable and main controls. In all cases considered, the main results are supported, i.e., the coefficient on the linear GDP per capita term maintains the same sign, is not too dissimilar in size, and remains statistically significant. Note that, in the main results, non-linearities are allowed for by estimating piecewise linear effects, i.e., average effects for different income groupings of countries.
7 We note two points relating to these inequalities. First, it does not matter whether E, Y and G are measured in real or nominal terms, provided both the numerator and denominator of the relevant ratio are measured in the same nominal or real terms (using the same deflator). Second, the same estimated size of the public sector in any one country, as given by sources such as the IMF, cannot simply be obtained by taking the quotient of the national effort and budget share for that country because these education spending measures are estimates. The quotient will give only a rough approximation of the size of government, especially for countries that have less accurate education spending data.
Disclosure statement
The authors have no potential conflict of interest to report.
References
Adserà, A. and Boix, C., 2002. Trade, democracy, and the size of the public sector: The political underpinnings of openness. International Organization, 56(2), pp. 229-262 [ CrossRef]
Afonso, A. and Alves, J., 2017. Reconsidering Wagner’s Law: Evidence from the functions of the government. Applied Economics Letters, 24(5), pp. 346-350 [ CrossRef]
Akanbi, O. A. and Schoeman, N. J., 2010. The determinants of public expenditure and expenditure on education in particular in a selection of African countries. South African Journal of Economic and Management Sciences, 13(1), pp. 50-61 [ CrossRef]
Angelov, A. G., 2019. Public expenditure on education in the EU member states: A cluster analysis. Economic Archive, 72(1), pp. 52-64.
Avelino, G., Brown, D. S. and Hunter, W., 2005. The effects of capital mobility, trade openness, and democracy on social spending in Latin America, 1980-1999. American Journal of Political Science, 49(3), pp. 625-641 [ CrossRef]
Baqir, R., 2002. Social sector spending in a panel of countries. IMF Working Paper, No. 02/35 [ CrossRef]
Baum, M. A. and Lake, D. A., 2003. The political economy of growth: Democracy and human capital. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), pp. 333-347 [ CrossRef]
Baumol, W. J. and Bowen, W. G., 1966. Performing arts – The economic dilemma. A study of problems common to theater, opera, music and dance. New York, NY: The Twentieth Century Fund.
Brown, D. S. and Hunter, W., 1999. Democracy and social spending in Latin America, 1980-92. American Political Science Review, 93(4), pp. 779-790 [ CrossRef]
Brown, D. S. and Hunter, W., 2004. Democracy and human capital formation: Education spending in Latin America, 1980 to 1997. Comparative Political Studies, 37(7), pp. 842-864 [ CrossRef]
Bursztyn, L., 2016. Poverty and the political economy of public education spending: Evidence from Brazil. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(5), pp. 1101-1128 [ CrossRef]
Busemeyer, M. R., 2007. Determinants of public education spending in 21 OECD democracies, 1980-2001. Journal of European Public Policy, 14(4), pp. 582-610 [ CrossRef]
Busemeyer, M. R., 2008. The impact of fiscal decentralisation on education and other types of spending. Swiss Political Science Review, 14(3), pp. 451-481 [ CrossRef]
Busemeyer, M. R., 2009. Social democrats and the new partisan politics of public investment in education. Journal of European Public Policy, 16(1), pp. 107-126 [ CrossRef]
Cameron, A. C. and Miller, D. L., 2015. A practitioner’s guide to cluster-robust inference. Journal of Human Resources, 50(2), pp. 317-372 [ CrossRef]
Cameron, D. R., 1978. The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis. American Political Science Review, 72(4), pp. 1243-1261 [ CrossRef]
Castles, F. G., 1989. Explaining public education expenditure in OECD nations. European Journal of Political Research, 17(4), pp. 431-448 [ CrossRef]
Cockx, L. and Francken, N., 2016. Natural resources: A curse on education spending? Energy Policy, 92, pp. 394-408 [ CrossRef]
Dragomirescu-Gaina, C., 2015. An empirical inquiry into the determinants of public education spending in Europe. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies, 4(25), pp. 1-24 [ CrossRef]
Driscoll, J. C. and Kraay, A. C., 1998. Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(4), pp. 549-560 [ CrossRef]
Feenstra, R. C., Inklaar, R. and Timmer, M. P., 2015. The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, 105(10), pp. 3150-3182 [ CrossRef]
Fosu, A. K., 2010. The external debt-servicing constraint and public-expenditure composition in sub-Saharan Africa. African Development Review, 22(3), pp. 378-393 [ CrossRef]
Freedom House, 2016. Freedom in the world survey data.
Garrett, G., 1998a. Global markets and national politics: Collision course or virtuous circle? International Organization, 52(4), pp. 787-824 [ CrossRef]
Garrett, G., 1998b. Partisan politics in the global economy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Garrett, G., 2001. Globalization and government spending around the world. Studies in Comparative International Development, 35(4), pp. 3-29 [ CrossRef]
Garritzmann, J. L. and Seng, K., 2016. Party politics and education spending: Challenging some common wisdom. Journal of European Public Policy, 23(4), pp. 510-530 [ CrossRef]
Hamilton, L. C., 1991. How robust is robust regression? Stata Technical Bulletin, 2, pp. 21-26.
Harding, R. and Stasavage, D., 2014. What democracy does (and doesn’t do) for basic services: School fees, school inputs, and African elections. Journal of Politics, 76(1), pp. 229-245 [ CrossRef]
Holcombe, R. G., 2005. Government growth in the twenty-first century. Public Choice, 124(1-2), pp. 95-114 [ CrossRef]
Huber, E., Mustillo, T. and Stephens, J. D., 2008. Politics and social spending in Latin America. Journal of Politics, 70(2), pp. 420-436 [ CrossRef]
Iversen, T. and Stephens, J. D., 2008. Partisan politics, the welfare state, and three worlds of human capital formation. Comparative Political Studies, 41(4/5), pp. 600-637 [ CrossRef]
Katzenstein, P. J., 1985. Small states in world markets. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Kaufman, R. R. and Segura-Ubiergo, A., 2001. Globalization, domestic politics, and social spending in Latin America: A time-series cross-section analysis, 1973-97. World Politics, 53(4), pp. 553-587 [ CrossRef]
Kuckuck, J., 2014. Testing Wagner’s law at different stages of economic development. FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis, 70(1), pp. 128-168 [ CrossRef]
Lake, D. A. and Baum, M. A., 2001. The invisible hand of democracy: Political control and the provision of public services. Comparative Political Studies, 34(6), pp. 587-621 [ CrossRef]
Murshed, S. M., Bergougui, B., Badiuzzaman, M. and Pulok, M. H., 2022. Fiscal capacity, democratic institutions and social welfare outcomes in developing countries. Defence and Peace Economics, 33(3), pp. 280-305 [ CrossRef]
Newey, W. K. and West, K. D., 1987. A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55(3), pp. 703-708.
Newey, W. K. and West, K. D., 1994. Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Review of Economic Studies, 61(4), pp. 631-653 [ CrossRef]
Ozkok, Z., 2017. Financing education in Europe: The globalization perspective. Economics & Politics, 29(1), pp. 69-90 [ CrossRef]
Peacock, A. and Scott, A., 2000. The curious attraction of Wagner's law. Public Choice, 102(1-2), pp. 1-17 [ CrossRef]
Ram, R., 1995. Public educational expenditures in the United States: An analytical comparison with other industrialized countries. Economics of Education Review, 14(1), pp. 53-61 [ CrossRef]
Rodrik, D., 1998. Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), pp. 997-1032 [ CrossRef]
Ruggie, J. G., 1982. International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), pp. 379-415 [ CrossRef]
Schneider, F. and Enste, D. H., 2000. Shadow economies: Size, causes, and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), pp. 77-114 [ CrossRef]
Schultz, T. P., 1988. Expansion of public school expenditures and enrollments: Intercountry evidence on the effects of income, prices, and population growth. Economics of Education Review, 7(2), pp. 167-183 [ CrossRef]
Shin, D., 2020. The military in politics and democracy: Its impact on government spending for education and health. Social Science Quarterly, 101(5), pp. 1810-1826 [ CrossRef]
Stasavage, D., 2005. Democracy and education spending in Africa. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 343-358 [ CrossRef]
Tilak, J. B. G., 1989. The recession and public investment in education in Latin America. Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, 31(1-2), pp. 125-146 [ CrossRef]
Wagner, A., 1892. Grundlegung der politischen ökonomie (3rd ed.). Leipzig: Winter.
Wagner, A., 1958. Three extracts on public finance. In: R. A. Musgrave and A. T. Peacock, eds. Classics in the theory of public finance. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 1-15.
Walter, S., 2010. Globalization and the welfare state: Testing the microfoundations of the compensation hypothesis. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2), pp. 403-426 [ CrossRef]
Adserà, A. and Boix, C., 2002. Trade, democracy, and the size of the public sector: The political underpinnings of openness. International Organization, 56(2), pp. 229-262 [ CrossRef]
Afonso, A. and Alves, J., 2017. Reconsidering Wagner’s Law: Evidence from the functions of the government. Applied Economics Letters, 24(5), pp. 346-350 [ CrossRef]
Akanbi, O. A. and Schoeman, N. J., 2010. The determinants of public expenditure and expenditure on education in particular in a selection of African countries. South African Journal of Economic and Management Sciences, 13(1), pp. 50-61 [ CrossRef]
Angelov, A. G., 2019. Public expenditure on education in the EU member states: A cluster analysis. Economic Archive, 72(1), pp. 52-64.
Avelino, G., Brown, D. S. and Hunter, W., 2005. The effects of capital mobility, trade openness, and democracy on social spending in Latin America, 1980-1999. American Journal of Political Science, 49(3), pp. 625-641 [ CrossRef]
Baqir, R., 2002. Social sector spending in a panel of countries. IMF Working Paper, No. 02/35 [ CrossRef]
Baum, M. A. and Lake, D. A., 2003. The political economy of growth: Democracy and human capital. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), pp. 333-347 [ CrossRef]
Baumol, W. J. and Bowen, W. G., 1966. Performing arts – The economic dilemma. A study of problems common to theater, opera, music and dance. New York, NY: The Twentieth Century Fund.
Brown, D. S. and Hunter, W., 1999. Democracy and social spending in Latin America, 1980-92. American Political Science Review, 93(4), pp. 779-790 [ CrossRef]
Brown, D. S. and Hunter, W., 2004. Democracy and human capital formation: Education spending in Latin America, 1980 to 1997. Comparative Political Studies, 37(7), pp. 842-864 [ CrossRef]
Bursztyn, L., 2016. Poverty and the political economy of public education spending: Evidence from Brazil. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(5), pp. 1101-1128 [ CrossRef]
Busemeyer, M. R., 2007. Determinants of public education spending in 21 OECD democracies, 1980-2001. Journal of European Public Policy, 14(4), pp. 582-610 [ CrossRef]
Busemeyer, M. R., 2008. The impact of fiscal decentralisation on education and other types of spending. Swiss Political Science Review, 14(3), pp. 451-481 [ CrossRef]
Busemeyer, M. R., 2009. Social democrats and the new partisan politics of public investment in education. Journal of European Public Policy, 16(1), pp. 107-126 [ CrossRef]
Cameron, A. C. and Miller, D. L., 2015. A practitioner’s guide to cluster-robust inference. Journal of Human Resources, 50(2), pp. 317-372 [ CrossRef]
Cameron, D. R., 1978. The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis. American Political Science Review, 72(4), pp. 1243-1261 [ CrossRef]
Castles, F. G., 1989. Explaining public education expenditure in OECD nations. European Journal of Political Research, 17(4), pp. 431-448 [ CrossRef]
Cockx, L. and Francken, N., 2016. Natural resources: A curse on education spending? Energy Policy, 92, pp. 394-408 [ CrossRef]
Dragomirescu-Gaina, C., 2015. An empirical inquiry into the determinants of public education spending in Europe. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies, 4(25), pp. 1-24 [ CrossRef]
Driscoll, J. C. and Kraay, A. C., 1998. Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(4), pp. 549-560 [ CrossRef]
Feenstra, R. C., Inklaar, R. and Timmer, M. P., 2015. The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, 105(10), pp. 3150-3182 [ CrossRef]
Fosu, A. K., 2010. The external debt-servicing constraint and public-expenditure composition in sub-Saharan Africa. African Development Review, 22(3), pp. 378-393 [ CrossRef]
Freedom House, 2016. Freedom in the world survey data.
Garrett, G., 1998a. Global markets and national politics: Collision course or virtuous circle? International Organization, 52(4), pp. 787-824 [ CrossRef]
Garrett, G., 1998b. Partisan politics in the global economy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Garrett, G., 2001. Globalization and government spending around the world. Studies in Comparative International Development, 35(4), pp. 3-29 [ CrossRef]
Garritzmann, J. L. and Seng, K., 2016. Party politics and education spending: Challenging some common wisdom. Journal of European Public Policy, 23(4), pp. 510-530 [ CrossRef]
Hamilton, L. C., 1991. How robust is robust regression? Stata Technical Bulletin, 2, pp. 21-26.
Harding, R. and Stasavage, D., 2014. What democracy does (and doesn’t do) for basic services: School fees, school inputs, and African elections. Journal of Politics, 76(1), pp. 229-245 [ CrossRef]
Holcombe, R. G., 2005. Government growth in the twenty-first century. Public Choice, 124(1-2), pp. 95-114 [ CrossRef]
Huber, E., Mustillo, T. and Stephens, J. D., 2008. Politics and social spending in Latin America. Journal of Politics, 70(2), pp. 420-436 [ CrossRef]
Iversen, T. and Stephens, J. D., 2008. Partisan politics, the welfare state, and three worlds of human capital formation. Comparative Political Studies, 41(4/5), pp. 600-637 [ CrossRef]
Katzenstein, P. J., 1985. Small states in world markets. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Kaufman, R. R. and Segura-Ubiergo, A., 2001. Globalization, domestic politics, and social spending in Latin America: A time-series cross-section analysis, 1973-97. World Politics, 53(4), pp. 553-587 [ CrossRef]
Kuckuck, J., 2014. Testing Wagner’s law at different stages of economic development. FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis, 70(1), pp. 128-168 [ CrossRef]
Lake, D. A. and Baum, M. A., 2001. The invisible hand of democracy: Political control and the provision of public services. Comparative Political Studies, 34(6), pp. 587-621 [ CrossRef]
Murshed, S. M., Bergougui, B., Badiuzzaman, M. and Pulok, M. H., 2022. Fiscal capacity, democratic institutions and social welfare outcomes in developing countries. Defence and Peace Economics, 33(3), pp. 280-305 [ CrossRef]
Newey, W. K. and West, K. D., 1987. A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55(3), pp. 703-708.
Newey, W. K. and West, K. D., 1994. Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Review of Economic Studies, 61(4), pp. 631-653 [ CrossRef]
Ozkok, Z., 2017. Financing education in Europe: The globalization perspective. Economics & Politics, 29(1), pp. 69-90 [ CrossRef]
Peacock, A. and Scott, A., 2000. The curious attraction of Wagner's law. Public Choice, 102(1-2), pp. 1-17 [ CrossRef]
Ram, R., 1995. Public educational expenditures in the United States: An analytical comparison with other industrialized countries. Economics of Education Review, 14(1), pp. 53-61 [ CrossRef]
Rodrik, D., 1998. Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), pp. 997-1032 [ CrossRef]
Ruggie, J. G., 1982. International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), pp. 379-415 [ CrossRef]
Schneider, F. and Enste, D. H., 2000. Shadow economies: Size, causes, and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), pp. 77-114 [ CrossRef]
Schultz, T. P., 1988. Expansion of public school expenditures and enrollments: Intercountry evidence on the effects of income, prices, and population growth. Economics of Education Review, 7(2), pp. 167-183 [ CrossRef]
Shin, D., 2020. The military in politics and democracy: Its impact on government spending for education and health. Social Science Quarterly, 101(5), pp. 1810-1826 [ CrossRef]
Stasavage, D., 2005. Democracy and education spending in Africa. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 343-358 [ CrossRef]
Tilak, J. B. G., 1989. The recession and public investment in education in Latin America. Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, 31(1-2), pp. 125-146 [ CrossRef]
Wagner, A., 1892. Grundlegung der politischen ökonomie (3rd ed.). Leipzig: Winter.
Wagner, A., 1958. Three extracts on public finance. In: R. A. Musgrave and A. T. Peacock, eds. Classics in the theory of public finance. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 1-15.
Walter, S., 2010. Globalization and the welfare state: Testing the microfoundations of the compensation hypothesis. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2), pp. 403-426 [ CrossRef]
|
|
|
September, 2023 III/2023
|